A POLICY FOR PRO POOR GROWTH IN PAKISTAN
By
Dr. Akmal Hussain
Senior Fellow,
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
Paper presented at the UNDP/PIDE Symposium on Pro-Poor Growth Policies,
The Marriott, Islamabad, 17th March 2003 and later published in: Towards Pro Poor
Growth Policies in Pakistan, (A joint publication of UNDP/PIDE), Islamabad, 2003.Page 1 of 23
A POLICY FOR PRO POOR GROWTH IN PAKISTAN
By
Dr. Akmal Hussain
INTRODUCTION
Designing a policy for pro poor growth involves addressing the structural features
of Pakistan’s growth process which constrain its capacity at the macro level for poverty
reduction. At the same time it is necessary to come to grips with the nature of the poverty
process at the local level. Poverty occurs when the individual is isolated from the
community and is locked into a nexus of power, which deprives the poor of their actual
and potential income. The poor face a structure of markets, state, and institutions, which
discriminate against their access over resources, public services and government
decision-making1
. In this context overcoming poverty means empowering the poor at the
local level. The challenge of pro poor growth therefore is to re-orient both the structure of
the economy as well as the local structures of power in favour of the poor.
This paper articulates a broad strategy of pro poor growth which could be
designed to optimize four parameters: (a) achieve higher GDP growth with a relatively
low investment (i.e. have a low incremental capital output ratio); (b) generate higher
employment for given growth rates of GDP; (c) generate higher exports; (d) achieve
greater equity and poverty reduction. The paper is organized into four sections as
follows:
Section I summarizes some of the major structural features of the economy and
the poverty process that need to be addressed in such a strategy; section II outlines a
strategy that can achieve both faster growth and faster poverty reduction; section-III gives
1
For a more detailed analysis of this phenomenon, See: Akmal Hussain: Pro Poor Growth,
Participatory Development and Decentralization: Paradigms and Praxis, chapter in: P. Wignaraja
et.al. (ed): Pro-Poor Growth and Governance in South Asia, Case Profiles, Oxford University
Press (forthcoming).
Note: The author wishes to thank Dr. Faiz Bilquees for helpful suggestions on an earlier
draft of the paper. Page 2 of 23
an outline of an approach for a direct attack on poverty through Participatory
Development at the local level. This constitutes a vital element not only in alleviating
poverty but also faster GDP growth: Participatory Development enables the poor
communities to acquire new skills, increase their productivity, incomes and investment.
This would enable them to overcome their poverty and simultaneously contribute to a
faster and more equitable GDP growth. In section IV we draw on some lessons from the
experience of decentralization reforms from South Asian countries in the context of
poverty, growth and empowerment; and finally section-V summarizes the main policy
conclusions of the paper.
I. STRUCTURAL FACTORS IN SLOW GROWTH AND RISING POVERTY
We begin by identifying the major features of the crisis in the real economy that
need to be addressed. These are:
I.1 Governance, Poverty and Unemployment
Poverty and inequality have increased during the 1990s due to the decline in GDP
growth, coupled with a decline in employment elasticities, labour productivity, and real
wages in both the agriculture and the industrial sector (see tables 1, 2, and 3). At the same
the economic burden of the poor intensified in the 90’s due to serious lapses in three
major aspects of governance:
(i) Due to poor financial management by successive governments particularly during
the 1990s, both the level of development expenditure and the efficiency of its use
declined. This contributed to the decay in the already inadequate social
infrastructure, a slow down in GDP growth, and rising poverty.
(ii) The failure to control budget deficits combined with the attempt to finance them
through indirect taxation also contributed to the increase in poverty, since the
adverse impact of such taxation had a relatively greater impact on the poor2
.
2
For example, the tax burden as a percentage of income was highest at 6.8% for the lowest income
group and lowest at –4.3% for the highest income group. See: Overcoming Poverty, The Report of
the Task Force on Poverty Eradication, May 1997. Page 3 of 23
(iii) During the 1990s the unprecedented level of corruption in the government, had a
significant adverse impact on economic growth and poverty. The cost of such
corruption to the banking sector alone has been estimated at around 10 to 15
percent of the GDP in 1996-1997; and the overall cost to the country of corruption
at the highest level of government was 20% to 25% of the GDP, which was
approximately US $ 15 billion in the same period3
.
Widespread corruption in government may have contributed to increasing
poverty in three ways: (a) the rising magnitude of corruption over time and at
different levels of decision making in the government may have been a major
factor in the uncertain policy environment and a constraint to estimating accurate
project feasibilities. This would be expected to slow down investment growth and
employment; (b) the transfer of resources to corrupt politicians and government
officials to be used at their discretion, and the resulting misuse and
misappropriation, rather than productive investment, could also be a factor in the
slowing down of the GDP growth; (c) the financial cost of individual projects
increased, thereby simultaneously slowing down GDP growth for given levels of
investment and also reducing the employment elasticities with respect to
investment.
TABLE 1
INCIDENCE OF POVERTY DURING THE 1990s
POVERTY INDEX 1992-93
HIES
1993-94
HIES
1996-97
HIES
1998-99
PIHS
Head-count 26.6 29.3 26.3 32.2
Poverty gap 4.5 5.5 4.5 6.9
Severity of poverty 1.2 1.5 1.2 2.2
SOURCE: Federal Bureau of Statistics, April 2001.
3
Burki, Pakistan: Fifty Years of Nationhood, Vanguard Books, Lahore, Page 174. Page 4 of 23
TABLE 2
INCOME INEQUALITY (GINI INDEX) DURING THE 1990s
REGION AND PROVINCE 1992-93
HIES
1993-94
HIES
1996-97
HIES
1998-99
PIHS
Pakistan 26.85 27.09 25.85 30.19
Urban areas 31.70 30.70 28.77 35.96
Rural areas 23.89 23.45 22.65 25.21
SOURCE: Federal Bureau of Statistics, April 2001.
TABLE 3
GROWTH OF GDP, EMPLOYMENT AND PRODUCTIVITY IN TWO
DECADES
Percent
GROWTH 1980s 1990s
1. GDP GROWTH 6.3 4.2
2. EMPLOYMENT GROWTH (TOTAL)
(i) Agriculture
(ii) Manufacturing
2.4
1.9
1.4
2.4
1.6
-0.4
3. PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH (TOTAL)
(i) Agriculture
(ii) Manufacturing
3.9
2
7
1.8
1.7
4.6
SOURCE: Nomaan Majid, Pakistan: An Employment Strategy, ILO/SAAT, December
1997 (Mimeo), Table A5, Page 58.
I.1.1 Policy Implications: Our analysis in this section shows that the most important
underlying factors in rising poverty during the 1990s were slower growth, rising capital
output ratios, falling employment elasticities, increased corruption and inefficiency of
public expenditure. Therefore a pro poor growth policy should aim to: (a) induce higher
investment, reduce incremental capital output ratios, and increase employment elasticities Page 5 of 23
with respect to both output and capital in order to increase employment; (b) increase the
level and efficiency of government development expenditure to increase employment; (c)
increase transparency of governance and reduce corruption to alleviate poverty. (d)
Improve the efficiency of institutions responsible for delivering public services to
alleviate poverty.
I.2 Health and Poverty
Research for the National Human Development Report (NHDR), suggests that the
high prevalence of disease amongst those who are slightly above the poverty line is a
major factor in pushing them into poverty. Those who are already poor get pushed into
deeper poverty as the result of loss of income and high medical costs resulting from
illness. The data show that on average 65% of the extremely poor were ill at the time of
the survey, and they had on average suffered from their illness for 95 days. The survey
data also show that the poor predominantly go to private allopathic practitioners rather
than to basic health units or government hospitals. Private medical facilities in rural areas
and small towns have grossly inadequate diagnostic facilities and there is wide spread
prevalence of spurious drugs in private sector retail outlets. Consequently when the poor
fall ill they suffer for a protracted period and get locked into a high cost source of
medical treatment. This erodes whatever little asset base they have, and pushes them into
indebtedness and deeper poverty4
.
The NHDR data on the widespread prevalence of disease in Pakistan is supported
by evidence from the National Health Survey of Pakistan5
, which shows that in rural
areas the prevalence of fair plus poor health for females above 25 years is as high as 75%,
while that for the males in the same age group is 45%. The curative health care system
has expanded substantially during the last decade (for example, the population per doctor
has fallen from 2082 in 1990 to 1529 in the year 2000), yet the high incidence of disease
points to both inadequate coverage and poor quality of the health care system in Pakistan.
4
Poverty, Growth and Governance, NHDR, UNDP, (Forthcoming).
5
National Health Survey of Pakistan, Pakistan Medical Research Council, Federal Bureau of
Statistics, Pakistan and the Department of Health and Human Services, USA, 1998, Page 127.
Food note 5 appears to be three references, if so please give their dates and publication refer to, as
well as the publishing agency. Page 6 of 23
I.2.1 Policy Implications: Since the UNDP, NHDR study shows that health is a major
factor that pushes people into poverty, clearly improved nutrition and health conditions
are important for poverty reduction. Improving the nutrition, preventive hygiene,
provision of safe drinking water, improving the service delivery of basic health units, and
improved diagnostic and treatment capabilities of Tehsil and District Hospitals are urgent
imperatives to deal with the crisis of health and poverty.
I.3 Asymmetric Markets, Local Power Structures and Poverty
The NHDR/PIDE survey data6
shows that the poor peasants face adverse input
and output markets. They have to pay relatively higher prices for their inputs and get
relatively lower prices for their outputs compared to the large farmers. At the same time,
due to the lack of access to formal credit markets, the poor peasants often have to borrow
from the landlord. As a consequence they are obliged to work on the landlord’s farm at
less than market wage rates. The NHDR study shows that the poor peasants could be
losing one third of their income due to asymmetric markets for inputs and outputs.
In the urban and semi urban areas where the poor households are predominantly
involved in micro enterprises the data shows that low incomes are primarily due to low
productivity and profitability of these micro enterprises.
I.3.1 Policy Implications: The evidence shows that asymmetric markets and local
power structures constitute structural factors in persistent poverty. They siphon off as
much as one third of the actual incomes of the poor, deprive them of their potential
savings and keep their productivity and incomes at a low level. A pro poor policy must
address these structural factors if poverty is to be overcome on a sustainable basis. Better
access for the poor over the markets for labour, land, agricultural inputs and outputs,
means changing the balance of power in favour of the poor at the local level. This
requires facilitating emergence of autonomous organisations of the poor, particularly
poor women at the village, Union Council, Tehsil and district levels. It also means
6
This survey was part of the study embodied in the National Human Development Report, UNDP,
Forthcoming. Page 7 of 23
enabling the poor to access credit, training, and technical support for increased
employment, productivity, and incomes.
I.4 Institutional Factors in Slow and Unstable Crop Sector Growth7
In agriculture the average annual growth rate of major crops has declined from
3.34% during the eighties to 2.38% in the nineties. At the same time, the frequency of
negative growth years in some of the major crops has increased. The slow down in
growth and increased instability of output in major crops has resulted in sharp increase in
rural poverty on the one hand, and a slow down in the export growth on the other.
Underlying this phenomenon are five major institutional constraints:
(a) Reduced water availability at the farm gate due to poor maintenance of the
irrigation system and low irrigation efficiencies of about 37 percent. While the
availability of irrigation water has been reduced, the requirement of water at
the farm level has increased due to increased deposits of salts on the top soil
and the consequent need for leaching. About 33 million tons of salts are
annually brought into the Indus Basin Irrigation System, out of which 24
million tons are being retained.8
(b) What makes improved efficiency of irrigation even more important is that the
extensive margin of irrigated acreage has been reached, so the future
agricultural growth will have to rely on improving the efficiency of water use
and other inputs. Thus the rehabilitation of Pakistan's irrigation system for
improving irrigation efficiency has become a crucial policy challenge for
sustainable agriculture growth.
(c) It is well known that high yielding varieties of seeds gradually lose their
potency through re-use, changing micro structure of soils, and changing
7
This sub-section is based on research paper by Akmal Hussain: (Employment Generation, Poverty
Alleviation and Growth in Pakistan’s Rural Sector: Policies for Institutional Change, Report
prepared for the ILO/CEPR, (Mimeo), March 1999.
8
Interim Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, Government of Pakistan, November 2001, Page 23. Page 8 of 23
ecology of micro organisms in the top soil. Therefore, breeding of more
vigorous seed varieties adapted to local environmental conditions, and their
diffusion amongst farmers through an effective research and extension
programme is necessary. Yet there is no organized seed industry in Pakistan to
meet the needs of farmers for the supply of vigorous varieties of seeds even in
the major crops. In wheat, for example, the average age of seeds in Pakistan is
11 years compared to an average of 7 years for all developing countries. It has
been shown that compared to India there was a sharp decline in growth of
total factor productivity in Pakistan after 1975, which can be attributed to the
poorer level of research and extension in Pakistan compared for example to
India.9
(d) A new dimension to the imperative of improving research capability in the
crop sector is indicated by the possibility of declining yields per acre related
with global warming. Given the sensitivity of wheat seed to temperature
increase, even a 2-degree centigrade increase in average summer temperatures
could mean an absolute yield decline of between 10 to 16 percent during the
21st century.10 With a 2.8 percent population growth, even a decline of 5
percent in yield per acre associated with global warming, could mean serious
food deficits for Pakistan. It is, therefore, necessary to develop heat resistant
varieties of food grains.
The current ineffectiveness of agriculture research and poor diffusion amongst
farmers is a cause for concern. This is particularly so in a situation where
future agriculture growth and labour absorption will have to depend more on
9
Mark W. Rosegrant and Robert Evenson: "Agricultural Productivity Growth in Pakistan and India:
A comparative Analysis", presented at Pakistan Institute of Development Economists Ninth
Annual General Meeting, Islamabad, 1993.
10 If atmospheric carbon is doubled, the average summer temperatures in Pakistan are expected to
increase by 1.5 C to 4.5 C (base average of 2.5 C), over the next 70 years. This could lead to a
decline in wheat yields from 10 percent to 60 percent, depending on the type of wheat seed,
planting time, related atmospheric/weather conditions. See: Qureshi, Ata and Iglesias:
Implications of Global Climate Change for Pakistan Agriculture: Impacts on Simulated Wheat
Production, Climate Institute, Washington, D. C. USA, 1992. Page 9 of 23
input efficiency than on enlargement of irrigated acreage; and input
intensification which were the major sources of agriculture growth in the past.
(e) One of the most important constraints to sustainable growth in the crop sector
is the degradation of soils, resulting from improper agricultural practices such
as: (i) lack of crop rotation and the resultant loss of humus in the top soil; (ii)
stripping of top soil and resultant loss of fertility associated with over grazing;
(iii) water erosion along hill sides and river banks due to cutting down of trees
and depletion of natural vegetation. According to one estimate, over 11
million hectares have been affected by water erosion and 5 million hectares by
wind erosion.11
TABLE 4
AVERAGE ANNUAL GROWTH RATE OF THE MANUFACTURING SECTOR
(VARIOUS PERIODS)
Period Small Scale Manufacturing LSM Total Manufacturing
1959/60 to 1969/70 2.85 12.43 9.24
1970/71 to 1979/80 7.21 4.84 5.50
1980/81 to 1989/90 8.40 8.16 8.21
1990/91 to 1995/96 7.88 4.40 5.59
1996/97 to 1999/2000 5.31 2.21 1.29
Source: Federal Bureau of Statistics, GOP.(Various Years) and Economic Survey of
Pakistan 2000-2001, Economic Advisor’s Wing, Ministry of Finance, GOP.
I.5 Some Constraints to the Growth of the Large Scale Manufacturing Sector
The growth rate of the large scale manufacturing sector was 12.43% in the period
1959/60 to 1969/70, and fell to 2.21% in the period 1996/97 to 1999/2000. (See table 4).
The factors underlying this dramatic decline include the following:
11 Alim Mian and Yasin Mirza: Pakistan Soil Resources, National Conservation Strategy, Sector
Paper IV, Environment and Urban Affairs Division, with IUCN, 1993. Page 10 of 23
(a) A fundamental structural constraint to industrial growth as indeed the underlying
factor in slow export growth, is the failure to diversify exports. The large scale
manufacturing output, particularly exports are concentrated in the traditional low
value added end of textiles.
(b) A changed pattern of global demand for industrial products with a shift towards
higher value added and knowledge intensive products. Pakistan’s industrial structure
was not positioned to respond quickly to these changed market conditions.
(c) An erosion of the domestic framework within which investment and growth is
sustained. This includes: (i) a continued threat to the life and property of citizens due
to the persistent poor law and order situation; (ii) high electricity tariffs and relatively
high interest rates (though the latter have fallen this year); (iii) lack of trained
professionals especially in the high skill sector; (iv) an inadequate technological base
through which industry can respond in a flexible way to changing patterns of
demand; (v) an adverse policy environment in the past within which tariff and export
incentives were distorted against those entrepreneurs who were seeking to improve
quality and productivity for export growth; (vi) dumping of smuggled, poor quality
and extremely low priced imported goods which are in many cases counterfeit copies
of branded Pakistani manufactured goods.
II. RESTRUCTURING GROWTH FOR FASTER POVERTY REDUCTION12
A four-pronged revival strategy needs to be undertaken in the light of the
structural constraints to growth and poverty alleviation discussed in Section I.
12 This section is based on a paper presented to the Federal Finance Minister in the Economic
Advisory Board, by Akmal Hussain: A Medium Term Strategy of Economic Revival, 15th
November 1999. (Also published in the daily Dawn on November 25 and 26, 1999).
Note: Some of the proposals related with agriculture sector have been incorporated in the Interim
Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper of the Government of Pakistan, November 2001, Pages 22 and
23. Page 11 of 23
II.1 Improving the Supply of Irrigation Water
Pakistan's irrigation system which is currently in a state of acute disrepair due to
decades of poor maintenance. The first element of the growth strategy should be a
national campaign on a war footing to rehabilitate it. Such a campaign would involve
organizing semi skilled labour for: (i) the desilting of canals; (ii) strengthening the banks;
(iii) organizing villagers for making “Pucca Khaalas” (concrete lined water courses); (iv)
improving the gradient of water courses and farmlands in order to improve both the
delivery and application efficiencies of irrigation.
Such a campaign being inherently labour intensive would not only generate
employment rapidly but also help to improve water availability and yields per acre at the
farm level. If the campaign is professionally designed and managed, the funding for
financing wage payments to the newly employed labour force could be sought from
multilateral agencies, some of which have poverty alleviation and sustainable agricultural
growth as their priority concerns. The district level development institutions in the local
government system could coordinate with union councils, village development councils,
and autonomous farmers associations to implement such a campaign.
II.2 Infrastructure Development
In addition to the campaign for improved maintenance of the irrigation system
other labour intensive infrastructure projects should also be undertaken to simultaneously
generate employment and stimulate aggregate demand in the economy. These include: (i)
building of farm to market roads; (ii) national high ways and ports; (iii) upgrading the
railway system and enlarging its transport capacity for bulk cargo; (iv) improved
communication system, and (iv) increased production of cheaper energy through
domestically available coal rather than imported furnace oil.13
13 In this regard the Planning Commission has formulated a valuable set of policy proposals for
energy development, See: Government of Pakistan, Planning Commission: Ten Year Perspective
Plan and Three Year Development Programme, Islamabad, September 1, 2001. Page 12 of 23
II.3 Milk, Marine Fisheries and High Value Added Agriculture Products
The third element of the revival strategy is to rapidly develop export led
production capacity for milk, fisheries, and high value added agricultural products such
as fruits, vegetables, and flowers. Let us illustrate this initiative by using the example of
milk. Pakistan is currently producing about 177 billion rupees worth of milk annually for
domestic consumption. This makes milk the largest agricultural product because
Pakistan's largest crop wheat, has an annual production value of about 111 billion rupees.
Unlike wheat however, the output of milk can be accelerated sharply within a couple of
years. Currently Pakistan's milch cattle yield per animal is one-fifth of the European
average. Demonstrable experience in the field has shown that the milk yields per animal
in Pakistan can be doubled within two years through scientific feeding, breeding, and
marketing. If the institutional framework could be established for training the farmers in
scientific feeding and breeding, and if the logistics could be set up to collect milk from
the farm door by means of refrigerated transport, milk output in Pakistan could be
doubled. This would have a dramatic impact not only on the incomes of the poor
peasants, but also on exports and overall GDP growth.
Pakistan lies at the hub of milk deficit regions such as Central Asia, West Asia
and South East Asia. Hence it could be argued that if milk output in Pakistan could be
doubled, export earnings would increase to such an extent that they would make a major
contribution to overcoming the balance of trade deficit. Such an initiative therefore can
lead to accelerated exports, higher GDP growth and improved income distribution in
Pakistan. A possible institutional framework for such an initiative could be the
establishment of dairy development boards at the provincial levels linked up with the
development institutions at the district and union council levels in the local government
structure.
Marine Fisheries, also provide a significant potential for improving foreign
exchange earnings although not as large as the potential for milk. Here again, what is
required is improved institutional support and better management rather than huge
investments by the Government. The expansion in the export of marine fisheries is
constrained because the storage facilities for transportation do not match the international Page 13 of 23
quality standards. Currently alternate layers of fish and hard sharp edged ice are placed in
containers on the boats. Under the weight of upper layers of fish and the sharp edged ice,
fish at the lower layers are crushed, and the resultant bleeding causes putrefaction. To
avoid this, it is necessary to provide shelves for layered storage of fish in boats, topped by
dry ice, with fiberglass covers to maintain the European Union standards of minus 7o
C
temperature during transportation. An export potential of 300 million dollars exists over
the next three years if such improved management of the marine fisheries industry could
be achieved.
Similarly the high value added production and export of fruits, vegetables, and
flowers would require: (i) institutional support for improved quality of output; (ii)
improved grading and packaging; and (iii) refrigerated transport right up to the cargo
terminals for air freight to the export market.
II.4 Rapid Growth of Small Scale Enterprises
The fourth element of the strategy would be to provide the institutional support
necessary for the rapid growth of small scale enterprises. These SSEs. include high value
added units in light engineering automotive parts, moulds, dyes, machine tools and
electronics and computer software.
Training of a large number of software experts with requisite support in credit and
marketing could quickly induce a significant increase in software exports from Pakistan.
Pakistan could build a pool of software experts for a large increase in export earnings.
This would of course require a proactive government to establish joint ventures between
large software companies such as Microsoft and Pakistan’s private sector institutions
such as LUMS and INFORMATICS. The Ministry of Science and Technology is already
moving rapidly in facilitating the growth of information technology in Pakistan. In this
sub-section however we will focus on small scale manufacturing enterprises.
Small scale industries have a low gestation period, are labour intensive, and can
generate a larger output per unit of investment compared to the large scale manufacturing
sector. Therefore the rapid growth of small scale enterprises would not only accelerate
economic growth in the medium term at relatively low levels of investment, but would Page 14 of 23
also increase employment and exports for given levels of GDP growth. The key strategic
issue in accelerating the growth of SSEs is to enable them to shift to the high value
added, high growth end of the product market.
A large number of small scale enterprises (SSEs) in the Punjab and the North
Western Frontier Province (NWFP) have a considerable potential for growth and high
value added production such as components for engineering goods or components of high
quality farm implements for the large scale manufacturing sector.14 Yet they are in many
cases producing low value added items like steel shutters or car exhaust pipes resulting in
low profitability, low savings and slow growth.
II.4.1 Constraints to the Rapid Growth of SSEs: Small scale enterprises in small towns
of Pakistan face the following major constraints:
(i) Inability of small units to get vending contracts for the manufacture of
components from the large-scale manufacturing sector (LSM).
(ii) Due to lack of expertise in production management and the frequent
inability to achieve quality control it becomes difficult to meet tight
delivery schedules.
(iii) Lack of specific skills like advanced mill work, metal fabrication,
precision welding, all of which are needed for producing quality products
with low tolerances and precise dimensional control. In other cases
accounting and management skills may be inadequate.
(iv) Difficulty faced by small units in getting good quality raw materials,
which often can only be ordered in bulk (for which the small entrepreneurs
do not have the working capital), and from distant large cities.
(v) Lack of specialized equipment.
14 Akmal Hussain: Labour Absorption in Pakistan’s Rural Sector, Final Report, ILO/ARTEP
(Mimeo), 20th September 1989, Pages 21 to 23. Page 15 of 23
(vi) Absence of fabrication facilities such as forging, heat treatment and
surface treatment which are required for manufacture of high value added
products, but are too expensive for any one small unit to set up.
(vii) Lack of capital for investment and absence of credit facilities.
II.4.2 Overcoming the Constraints to the Growth of SSEs. Overcoming the
aforementioned constraints would involve providing institutional support in terms of
credit, quality control management, skill training and marketing. This could be done by
facilitating the establishment of industrial support centers (ISCs) located in the specified
growth nodes in selected towns where the entrepreneurial and technical potential as well
as markets already exist. Such support institutions (ISCs) while being facilitated by the
government and autonomous organizations such as SMEDA can and should be in the
private sector and market driven.
The concept of the Industrial Support Centers is based on the fact that small scale
industrialists in Pakistan have already demonstrated a high degree of entrepreneurship,
innovation and efficient utilization of capital. The ISCs would provide an opportunity for
rapid growth to SSEs through local participation in extension services, prototype
development, and diffusion of improved technologies, equipment, and management
procedures. The ISCs would constitute a decentralized system which ensures continuous
easy access to a comprehensive package of support services such as credit, skill training,
managerial advice and technical assistance. The ISCs could also be linked up with
national research centres, and donor, agencies for drawing upon technical expertise and
financial resources of these agencies in the service of small scale industries (SSI).
The Industrial Support Centres could have the following functional dimensions:
(i) Marketing
Provision of orders from the large scale manufacturing sector for components, and
from farmers for farm implements. These orders would then be sub-contracted to
the cluster of SSI units that the ISC is supposed to serve. The individual order Page 16 of 23
would be sub-contracted to the SSI on the basis of the skills and potential
strengths of the unit concerned.
(ii) Monitoring and Quality Control
Having given the sub-contract, the ISC would then monitor the units closely and
help pinpoint and overcome unit specific bottlenecks to ensure timely delivery
and quality control of the manufactured products. These bottlenecks may be
specialized skills, equipment, good quality raw material or credit.
(iii) Skill Training and Product Development.
Skill training for technicians could be provided by the new good quality
vocational training institutes (VTIs) established by the Vocational Training
Council of Punjab. Similar VTIs could be established in other provinces. The ISC
would provide specialized supplementary skill training on its premises to workers
in the satellite SSI units when required. At the same time, it would provide
advice on jigs, fixtures, special tools and product development where required.
(iv) Forging and Heat Treatment Facilities
The ISC's would establish at their premises plants for forging, heat treatment and
surface treatment. The SSI units could come to the ISC to get such fabrication
done on the products they are manufacturing on sub-contract, and pay a mutually
agreed price for this job to the ISC.
(v) Credit
The ISC would provide credit to the SSI's for purchase of new equipment and raw
materials. In cases where raw materials are available in bulk supply, the ISC
could buy it from the source, stock it on its premises and sell at a reasonable price
to units as and when they need them. Page 17 of 23
III DIRECT ATTACK ON POVERTY
Establishing the institutional basis for enabling the poor to increase their incomes,
savings and investment, would not only constitute a direct attack on poverty but would
also contribute to a faster and more equitable economic growth process. In this section
we examine the issue of empowerment of the poor with special reference to women. In
this context we will explore the institutional imperatives of making the newly emerging
local government structures more effective in achieving the empowerment of poor
women.
III.1 Empowerment and Autonomous Organizations of the Poor
(i) The Meaning of Empowerment: Since the term empowerment has been loosely
used in much of the literature on development it may be helpful to specify its meaning in
the context of this paper. Empowerment means enabling the poor to build their human
capabilities and economic resource base for breaking out of the poverty nexus. It is a
process of reconstructing a group identity, of raising consciousness, of acquiring new
skills and of achieving better access over markets and institutions for a sustainable
increase in incomes. Such a process progressively imparts to the poor a new power over
the economic and social forces that fashion their daily lives. It is through this power that
the poor shift out of the perception of being passive victims of the process that
perpetuates their poverty. Thus they become active subjects in initiating interventions that
progressively improve their economic and social condition to overcome poverty.
(ii) Empowering the Poor, Particularly Women: The fact that poor women in Pakistan
suffer from a double burden that of being poor and being women, the economic strategy
should require a national campaign to empower the poor at the level of village/mohallah,
Union Council, Tehsil and District. The idea is to facilitate the growth of community
organizations of the poor at the village/mohallah level and to enable poor women to form
their own autonomous community organizations to be able to break out of both the
poverty nexus and gender based discrimination. Through these COs the poor can identify
income generating projects, initially at the household level, acquire skill training from a
variety of sources such as government line departments, autonomous institutions, private Page 18 of 23
sector firms, NGOs. and donors; and access credit for micro enterprise projects through
apex organizations such as the PPAF, Khushali Bank, Small Business Finance
Corporation (SBFC), and commercial banks. Special organizational arrangements would
need to be made in these apex institutions to take credit to poor women and women’s
COs, since poor women have even lesser access over institutional credit compared to
poor men.
It is important that such village level community based organisations (CBOs) be
autonomous and be permitted to form cluster apex organisations with other CBOs.
Autonomous CBOs by means of social mobilisation, increased productivity through skill
training, increased income, savings and investment would begin a process of localised
capital accumulation. Such a process, which we have called Participatory Development15
would be integrally linked with the emergence of a new consciousness of empowerment.
The poor can begin to take autonomous initiatives to improve their material conditions of
life. They would thus break out of the poverty nexus and shift from being victims to
active subjects of social and economic change. Such a process of village level increases
in productivity, incomes and savings would not only constitute a direct attack on the
poverty problem but would also contribute to a faster and more equitable macro
economic growth16.
Such autonomous organizations of the poor could become not only a framework
for grassroots economic growth, but would also constitute countervailing power to that of
the power structures of local elites. At the same time, these autonomous organizations of
the poor would enable the individual poor household to get better access over input and
output markets.
15 The concept of Participatory Development is formulated in: Akmal Hussain: Pakistan, A Strategy
for Poverty Alleviation, Vanguard, Lahore, 1994, Pages 26 to 29.
Also see: P. Wignaraja, A. Hussain, H. Sethi & G. Wignaraja: Participatory Development:
Learning from South Asia, O.U.P, 1991.
16 For a more detailed discussion of this issue, See: Akmal Hussain: Poverty, Growth and
Governance, Chapter in, V.A. Pai Panandiker (ed.): Problems of Governance in South Asia,
Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi, 2000. Page 19 of 23
Facilitating the emergence of autonomous organizations of the poor particularly
organizations of poor women, could enable the newly established local government
institutions to function in a more equitable and effective manner. The equity would be
with respect to class as well as gender. This would require establishing institutionalized
links between autonomous organizations of the poor and local government bodies at the
Village, Union Council, Tehsil and District levels. These institutional links between
organizations of the poor and elected local bodies would enable more participatory and
equitable processes of project identification, design and implementation for local level
development.
III.2 Devolution for Empowerment Versus Decentralization
Almost every country in South Asia has undertaken decentralization reforms with
the stated purpose of empowering the poor and thereby achieving good governance. Yet
there are a number of pitfalls in the implementation of these reforms. As Pakistan
embarks on its own programme of devolution, it may be useful to point out that
devolution cannot simply be seen in terms of a decentralization of administrative
functions within existing government structures. Rather decentralization has to create the
space within which an institutionalized relationship can begin between autonomous
organizations of the poor and various tiers of local government.
A number of pitfalls can emerge in the implementation of devolution reforms.
Unless they are addressed at an early stage these reforms may not achieve the desired
objectives. The following four lessons may be drawn on the basis of case studies of
decentralization reforms in South Asian countries17:
(i) Formal decentralization of administrative power in itself does not necessarily help
the poor as pointed out by Upadhyay18 in the context of Nepal. Empowerment of
the poor, he argues, requires that formal decentralization must be accompanied by
17 See Akmal Hussain: Pro-Poor Growth, Participatory Development and Decentralization:
Paradigms and Praxis, Part-III of the forthcoming book: P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.) Pro
Poor Growth and Governance in South Asia – Case Profiles of Participatory Development and
Decentralization Reforms, Zed Press, London (Forthcoming)
18 See: S.K. Upadhyay, The Nepal Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.) Pro Poor
Growth and Governance in South Asia, op.cit. Annexure to Part-III. Page 20 of 23
a rigorous process of social mobilization. This involves consciousness raising,
conscientisation (would sensitization be a substitute for this) and building
organisations of the poor. It is only such a process that will enable the poor to
acquire countervailing power. Without this dimension of countervailing power,
decentralization will merely result in the appropriation by elites of the “fruits of
decentralization for their own narrow benefit”. In this context Ali19 makes an
important distinction between decentralization of administrative power in favour
of its regional/local offices as opposed to decentralization in favour of the local
people in case of Bangladesh. Apart from this it could be argued that in areas
where asymmetric structures of power prevail (for example, coalitions of rich
peasants/landlord, local influentials such as traders, revenue and police officials)
mere decentralization of administrative power could intensify the oppression of
the poor.
(ii) The second lesson emerging from the case studies is that if decentralization is to
enable empowerment of the poor, it must be holistic. i.e., it incorporates political
power, enhanced confidence, emergence of social consciousness, and
administrative and fiscal devolution. At the same time it must reach down to the
grass roots level through various intermediate levels, with institutionalized
participation of the poor in governance at every level. Upadhyay refers to this
holism and multi layered devolution in the Nepal case study.
(iii) The political dimension of decentralization must be inclusive and capable of
absorbing what Upadhyay calls “diverse ethnic and other identity groups as equal
partners occupying spaces in the polity”. He argues that the centralized polity
excludes such identities which may be a factor in ethnic strife and social
polarization. While the poor once organized are able to generate new resources at
the local level yet, as participatory development is scaled up, internally generated
resources may be insufficient. Therefore externally generated resources become
necessary but these have to be carefully applied through a sensitive support
19 See: Dr. Shaikh Maqsood Ali, The Bangladesh Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana
(ed.), op.cit., Annexure to Part-III. Page 21 of 23
system that strengthens rather than weakens the autonomy of the organisations of
the poor. Such a support system could be provided by a combination of apex
NGOs, state institutions, banks and local governments. Upadhyay emphasizes the
importance of such support organisations being sensitized by a pro poor
perspective.
(iv) In the case of urban areas it appears that communities who have developed their
own funds and managed development themselves are able to establish a more
equitable relationship with local government institutions20. It can be argued that to
enable urban communities to manage their own development it is necessary to
provide technical advice and managerial guidance. At the same time an
institutionalized process of consultation and coordination may be necessary
between urban community organizations and local government institutions to
prevent them from working at cross purposes.
POLICY CONCLUSIONS
(1) This paper proposes a policy of pro poor growth, which involves restructuring the
macro economic growth process on the one hand and local structures of power in favour
of the poor on the other. The poor at the local level are locked into a nexus of power
represented by markets, social groups and institutions, which deprive them of as much as
one third of their income. It has been argued that empowerment of the poor requires
facilitating the emergence of autonomous community based organizations of the poor
(CBOs) which can enable them to acquire improved access over markets, institutions, and
public resources for breaking out of the poverty nexus. These CBOs need to be
institutionally linked with various tiers of local government so that the poor can
participate in the decisions regarding the allocation of public resources at the local level,
and in the design and implementation of community level social infrastructure projects.
(2) On the basis of latest empirical evidence available it is seen that widespread ill
health in Pakistan is a major trigger that pushes people into poverty and the poor into
20 See: Arif Hassan, The Pakistan Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.), op.cit.,
Annexure to Part-III. Page 22 of 23
deeper poverty. It was proposed that urgent initiatives need to be undertaken for
preventive hygiene, provision of safe drinking water, improving the service delivery of
basic health units and improved diagnostic and treatment capabilities of Tehsil and
District hospitals.
(3) At the macro level, restructuring growth to enhance its poverty reduction
capability involves addressing four parameters: (a) achieve higher GDP growth with a
relatively low investment (i.e. have a low incremental capital output ratio); (b) generate
higher employment for given growth rates of GDP; (c) generate higher exports; (d)
achieve greater equity and poverty reduction.
Specifically a four pronged policy initiative is suggested to address these
parameters for pro poor growth: (i) a national campaign to rehabilitate Pakistan’s
Irrigation System to increase irrigation efficiencies so as to provide more water at the
farm level. Specifically this would involve building more dams, desilting and lining of
canals wherever possible, and building pucca khaalas. This would provide more water to
the farmers and increased employment; (ii) initiating infrastructure projects such as farm
to market roads, national highways and ports, upgrading the railway system and increased
production of cheaper energy through the domestically available coal rather than the
furnace oil. Since such projects have high employment elasticities they would help to
generate both employment and aggregate demand. (iii) facilitate the increased production
and exports of milk, marine fisheries and high value added agriculture products. (iv)
accelerate the growth of small-scale industries through the establishment of Industrial
Support Centres in the context of public/private partnership. These centres would aim at
providing unit specific support for marketing, quality control, skill and product
development, specialized fabrication facilities and credit. Page 23 of 23
References
1. Ali, S.M., (forthcoming), The Bangladesh Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.),
Pro-Poor Growth and Governance in South Asia, Case Profiles, Oxford University Press.
2. Burki, S.J., (1999), Pakistan: Fifty Years of Nationhood, Vanguard Books, Lahore
3. Government of Pakistan, (2001), Interim Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper, Policy Wing, Finance
Division, Islamabad.
4. Government of Pakistan, (2001), Ten Year Perspective Plan and Three Year Development
Programme, Planning Commission, Islamabad.
5. Hassan, Arif, (forthcoming), The Pakistan Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.),
Pro-poor Growth and Governance in South Asia, Case Profiles, Oxford University Press.
6. Hussain, Akmal, (1989), Labour Absorption in Pakistan’s Rural Sector, ILO/ARTEP.
7. Hussain, Akmal, (1994), Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, Vanguard Books, Lahore.
8. Hussain, Akmal, (1999), Employment Generation, Poverty Alleviation and Growth in Pakistan’s
Rural Sector: Policies for Institutional Change, Report prepared for the ILO/CEPR (Mimeo).
9. Hussain, Akmal, (1999), A Medium Term Strategy of Economic Revival, Paper presented to the
Federal Finance Minister of Pakistan, Islamabad.
10. Hussain, Akmal, (2000), “Poverty, Growth and Governance”, Chapter in: V.A. Pai Panandiker
(ed.): Problems of Governance in South Asia, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi.
11. Hussain, Akmal, (forthcoming), “Pro Poor Growth, Participatory Development and
Decentralization: Paradigms and Praxis”, Chapter in: P. Wignaraja et.al. (ed): Pro-Poor Growth
and Governance in South Asia, Case Profiles, Oxford University Press.
12. Hussain, Akmal, et al., (1997), Overcoming Poverty: The Report of the Task Force on Poverty
Eradication.
13. Hussain, Akmal with Kemal, A.R., Hamid, A.I., Mumtaz, K., Ali, Imran, and Qutub, A.,
(forthcoming), Poverty, Growth and Governance, NHDR, UNDP, OUP.
14. Mian, Alim and Mirza, Yasin, (1993), Pakistan Soil Resources, National Conservation Strategy,
Sector Paper IV, Environment and Urban Affairs Division, with IUCN.
15. National Health Survey of Pakistan, (1998), Pakistan Medical Research Council.
16. Qureshi, Ata and Iglesias, (1992), Implications of Global Climate Change for Pakistan
Agriculture: Impacts on Simulated Wheat Production, Climate Institute, Washington, D. C. USA.
17. Rosegrant, Mark W. and Evenson, Robert, (1993), Agricultural Productivity Growth in Pakistan
and India: A comparative Analysis, Paper presented at Pakistan Institute of Development
Economists, Ninth Annual General Meeting, Islamabad.
18. Upadhyay, S.K., (forthcoming), The Nepal Case Study, in P. Wignaraja and S. Sirivardana (ed.),
Pro Poor Growth and Governance in South Asia, Case Profiles, Oxford University Press.
19. Wignaraja, Ponna, Hussain, Akmal, Sethi, Harsh, and Wignaraja, Ganeshan, (1991), Participatory
Development, Learning from South Asia, United Nations University, Oxford University Press.
No comments:
Post a Comment