Tuesday, 17 February 2015

Poverty Alleviation In Pakistan

96 Annexure II ANNEXURE II RURAL INDUSTRALIZATION∗ ECONOMIC LOGIC AND INSTITUTIONAL REQUIREMENTS Introduction Since the crop sector still abs the majority of Pakistan’s population, there is a commonly held view that the key to the employment problem lies in accelerating agricultural growth. While faster growth of crop output is desirable on a number of grounds, the analysis in this Study shows that the crop sector cannot be expected to absorb more than 25 percent of the estimated increase in Pakistan’s population over the next decade. In the absence of a major policy intervention, there is of course. A trend towards concentration of growing population in large cities. However, given the prohibitive cost of even basic amenities in large cities, and extremely high cost of employment generation, the present trends of urbanization are not sustainable from an employment perspective. This study argues that t lie critical role of employment generation and population absorption will have to be Performed by a new rural industrialization drive, i.e., the non—crop sector in the rural areas, focused on a set of growth nodes located in the smaller towns of Pakistan. The present study examines first the existing trends in population growth Ii and urbanization, then presents a critical appraisal of the employment issue as it is dealt with by the NCA and the Planning Commission. Section III presents the results of our estimates of labour absorption capability in he crop sector over the period 1988 to 2000. In Section IV trends in labour absorption in the non—crop sector are indicated and in Section V analysis based on existing field survey data is presented to explain the paradox of localized labour shortages ∗ this annexure is drawn from Akmal Hussain: Rural Industrialization: Economic Logic and Institutional Requirements, Paper presented at the International Conference on: Agricultural Strategic for the 199s, Pakistan Association of Agricultural Social Scientists, Islamabad, 7-9 May 1991. This Paper is based on earlier research done for the ILO/ARTEP by the author, which was an input into the National Manpower Commission Report 1990. 96Annexure II 97 at peak seasons in agriculture in a “labour surplus” economy. In Sections VI and VII a detailed set of recommendations are made regarding the operational aspects of a policy to induce rural industrialization. I. TRENDS IN POPULATION GROWTH, URBANIZATION AND THE IMPERATIVE OF INCREASING LABOUR ABSORPTION IN AGRICULTURE PEPAC has generated three alternative forecasts of population by the year 2000, based on he Cohort—Survival Model which consists of a simulation of the real determinants of population growth. i.e., births and deaths, using the 19$ I census agestructure and (he 1976 PGS age-specific fertility and mortality rates) The resultant forecasts are as follows: i) If there is no change in fertility and mortality rates or mutually compensatory changes, then I lie population in the year 2000will he 147.7 million ii) If CFR decline from the current 41 / 1000 to 30.3/l000, population in the year 2000 will be 133.9 million. . However, if (more realistically) fertility decline occurs only after a significant decline in infant mortality, the resultant population will be 143.3 million. iii) The highest estimate (most realistic?) of 150 or 152 million is based on the assumptions of under— enumeration in the 1981 census, substantial return migration from the Middle East and permanent settlement of Afghan refugees in Pakistan. If we use a population estimate of 143 million (ii above), then at present rates of urbanization (4.7 percent per annum) the urban population by the year 2000 is estimated at 56.7 million. The urban settlement pattern suggests that the increase in urban population would be concentrated in the large cities. The question that now arises is, if there is no major policy intervention to increase labour absorption in agriculture, are existing urbanization trends sustainable? The 9798 Annexure II answer is apparent from (lie fact that at current infrastructure standards, the costs of population absorption in the urban areas is 6 times the cost of rural population absorption. This is because of (lie greater need for road access to houses, piped water supply and sewage disposal. Estimates of resource requirement of absorbing the expected 57 million urban population of the year 2000 at minimum current standards, even on the basis of a highly optimistic GDP growth rate of 6.9 percent per annum, turn out to be three limes the resource availability over the period2 . Thus, by the year 2000, as much as 60 percent of the urban population could be living in inservice localities (or Kachi Abadis) compared to about 25 percent today. It is in the context of this grim Prospect of a serious resource constraint in providing the minimum conditions of civilized life to the projected urban population, that the policy imperative of increasing labour absorption in the rural sector manifests itself. II. TRENDS IN EMPLOYMENT AND THE ISSUE OF RURAL LABOUR ABSORPTION The National Commission on Agriculture (NCA) in its Chapter on Manpower and Employment acknowledges the paucity of the database in these words: “Employment implications of (he projected course of agricultural development are difficult to estimate. Available labour force statistics are weak and subject to some doubt, which therefore permits little scope for an analysis of past trends and relationships3 . It is not surprising that the data base on rural employment and labour absorption in agriculture is weak. (This can be said for most developing countries.) However, what is surprising is that the National Commission on Agriculture made no attempt to work on the existing data to draw analytical conclusions. It could have used the labour force surveys, the census data and WAPDA data to do so. Yet, it merely brushes aside this task. What is worse is that the NCA then proceeds to make a number of heroic assertions that were politically 98Annexure II 99 comforting at the time, but served to sweep the problem of rural employment under the carpet of “agricultural growth For example, in referring to the Green Revolution phenomenon the NCA report says: “..... The growth of the cultivated acreage required more labour, even if the amount of labour per hectare and per individual crop was declining. Also, the larger volume of cm (put requires more labour tot harvesting, transportation to the market and post harvest operations.... These employment gains may have exceeded the negative impact from the shift in tenancy and associated demand for labour.” (Emphasis mine.)4 The fact that total output (luring the 1970s period was increasing especially in a situation where labour requirement “per hectare and per individual crop was declining” does not constitute adequate grounds to conclude that the overall employment effect during (lie Green Revolution period “may” have been positive. The net effect on employment (whether positive or negative) can only be determined by comparing a quantitative estimate of increased labour demand associated with increased cropping intensity and post harvest operations on the one hand, with the reduced man clays per acre requirement for each operation associated with the n ion of different product ion, harvesting and post harvesting operations on (lie other. In the absence of quantitative estimates of the impact on labour demand of- changes in cropping patterns, cropping intensities, and - mechanization of farm operations, the NCA conclusion that the overall labour demand during the Green Revolution period “may” have increased is more a cry of hope than a scientific assessment. In sharp contrast with the NCA treatment of the employment issue, the Planning Commission exercise for the Seventh Five Year Plan at least in its overall employment projection is based on empirical data and is also analytically sound. However, even the Seventh Five Year Plan document does not have much to say on the issue of rural labour absorption apart from a few general observations. Assuming no significant change ii the labour force participation rate, the Planning Commission estimates an 99100 Annexure II annual increase in the labour force seeking domestic employment during the period 1988-1993, to be 3.3 percent. (This includes an estimated 0.4 million net returnees from abroad during the same period.)5 Based on a preliminary exercise of sectoral employment elasticity with respect to real output, the Planning Commission estimates an overall employment elasticity of 0.4 during the period 1988-19936 . The following Table 1 indicates labour force and employment projections based on this elasticity estimate. The table shows that open unemployment is expected to increase from 1 million in I 988 to 2.4 million in 1993. Apart from open unemployment the major from which the problem manifests itself in Pakistan (as in many other developing countries) is under-employment. The Labour Force Survey (LFS) suggests that in 1986—87 under employment affected 10.5 percent of the labour force. The Planning Commission indicates that if a more strict criterion of full employment is used then upto one-third of the labour force needs more regular additional work. At existing trends, even to maintain open unemployment at existing levels, i.e., in order to absorb the new entrants to the labour force (luring the period 1988— 1993, ii would require au impossibly high growth rate of GDP of 8 percent. Alternatively, at a projected growth rate of 6.5 percent per annum over the period the employment elasticity would have to be increased to 0.5 percent. This would require a major new effort at a carefully formulated employment policy with an effective implementation mechanism. At a strategic level the new Employment Policy would have two interrelated dimensions: (i) increasing the labour absorption capacity of the rural sector. This is clearly necessary in a situation where the infrastructure Cost of population absorption in I he urban areas is six times greater than in rural areas; (ii) the rapid development of small-scale industries and associated infrastructure in small towns linked with the rural sector. The emphasis on small—scale industries within a new Employment Policy is necessary in view of the fact (hat the 100Annexure II 101 cost of au additional job in the large—scale manufacturing is 80 times the cost of a job in the small-scale industry. III. TRENDS IN LABOUR ABSORPTION IN THE CR01’ PRODUCT SECTOR 111.1 A Note on Method of Calculation i. I have attempted to estimate changes in labour absorption capability of the crop production sector under two different policy packages: Policy I in which a) The growth in the number and size of tractors during 1988—2000 follows the same trend as that observed in the earlier period. b) Mechanized harvesting does not become a major factor in agricultural production at the all Pakistan level. c) The potential For 38 MAF of additional irrigation at the farm gate through improved delivery efficiency and usable ground water resources is realized. Through such a policy it is assumed that crop production sector would grow at a compound rate of 3.7 percent per year during 1988-2000. Policy II would involve slowing down t lie growl h of tractors to 50 percent of the rate observed during I 968-75, ceteris paribus. ii. In estimating labour demand the agriculture census figures for cropped acreage under each crop for irrigated and unirrigated acreage respectively were combined With labour coefficient estimates for each crop for irrigated and unirrigated areas respectively, obtained from WAPDA XAES data.7 iii. The estimate of the overall increase in labour absorption in the C1O sector associated with a trend growth rate of 3.7 percent per annum in Policy I, takes account of the labour displacement effect of tractorization ion winch in this estimate is assumed to follow past trends. In the estimate for Policy II the negative effect of tractorization on labour demand is reduced because of the assumed slow down of the pace of tractorization. 101102 Annexure II iv. The estimates of the labour displacement of tractors are based on detailed crop-wise agriculture census data, tractorized and non-tractorized area under each crop and finally monthly labour requirements data for each crop obtained from WAPDA XAES data. It is interesting that my estimate of per tractor gross labour displacement through this method comes to 3,842 man day per year, i.e. 10.53 full-time labourers. This estimate is remarkably close to the World Bank Sample Survey results reported by MeInerney and Donaldson.8 They estimate the gross labour displacement effect per tractor to be 11 full-time labourers. The increase in labour demand over the period is a net effect resulting from the positive effect to increased yields and cropping intensity on the one hand and negative effect of tractorization on the other. v. Having estimated the net increase in labour demand over the period in terms of millions of man days per year, this figure is then translated into the number of households that can be absorbed in crop production through additional labour demand. This is done by estimating the number of man—days of paid labour required to sustain a household, on the basis of minimum expenditure necessary on household food, clothing, etc., and prevailing real wage rates. The conversion figure comes to 225. 11 man days of work required to sustain a household. The number of households expected to be additionally absorbed in the crop sector is easily converted into an estimate of population absorption by using the census figure of average agricultural household size (6.5). 111.2 Analyzing Results The table shows that if a 3.7 percent growth rate of crop production is maintained over the period with associated increases in cropping intensities and yields, then in spite of the existing- trend of tractorization, a net increase in labour demand of about 292.3 million, man days per year by the end of this century can be expected. This means an increase in absorption of households of around 1.297 million, or a total increase in population absorption of 8.4 million in the crop sector over the period. 102Annexure II 103 The increase in labour absorption in the crop sector increases substantially to 1.6 million households or 10.4 million people, if the pace of tractorization is slowed down through withdrawal of subsidies, tax exemptions and cheap credit facilities. The most important conclusion that emerges from these labour absorption estimates is that over the next decade the crop sector cannot be expected to bear the brunt of absorbing the projected population increase. Even with optimistic projections of labour absorption capability, the crop sector can absorb between 8 to 10 million additional people out of a possible population increase of over 30 million people between now at the end of the century. Therefore, if sustainable levels of urbanization are to be avoided, attention will have to be given to the lion-crop activities in the rural areas. These include livestock, social forestry, off-farm activities such as chicken hatcheries, fruit and food processing, cold storage, construct ion, infrastructure and rural industrialization. IV. TRENDS IN LABOUR ABSORPTION IN NON-FARM ACTIVITY IN THE AGRICULTURE SECTOR The following Table 3 provides an estimate of increases in non-farm labour absorption (luring the period 1988-2000. The figures have been estimated by applying the WAPDA XAES ratio of non—farm to l employment. This ratio was applied to my estimate labour absorption in the crop sector, for each policy package to get estimates in terms of man-days per year. These were divided (in each case) by my estimates of man—days per year required in to sustain a family with a standard of living just on the poverty line and with real wage rates prevailing in the rural sector in 1975. The resultant figures were multiplied by the Agriculture Census figure of the number of family members per non-farm rural household. It is important to point out that my estimates of non—farm population would be subject to the biases inherent in a ratio that assumes as temporally constant the relationship between the farm and non-farm sector. Apart from this weakness the non-farm population absorption figures are 103104 Annexure II dependent on the farm absorption figure. i.e., the possibility of autonomous economic activity such as rural industries is not taken into account. Table 3 shows that associated with the expected increase in labour absorption of the crop sector, an increase in absorption of about 2 million people can be expected in the non-farm agriculture sector. This points to the Fact that a mere increase in crop product ion cannot he expected to generate an adequate economic activity in the non—farm sect or Autonomous initiatives may be required (such as rural industrialization), if the potential for labour absorption of the rural sector is to be realized. V. AGRARIAN CHANGE AND THE COMPLEXITY OF THE LABOUR MARKET: A PRELIMINARY HYPOTHESIS V.1 The Simple Analytics of Agrarian Change and Demand for Farm Labour I have shown elsewhere that in Pakistan’s agriculture there is a tendency towards polarization in farms and farm area, i.e., over time the percentage share of farms (and farm area) at either end of the size class scale tends to increase, while the percent age share of the medium size class tends to decline. This observed polarization phenomenon is essentially induced by I lie tendency of in any large landowner to resume for owner cultivation some (through not necessarily all) of their land formerly rented out In tenants. Since the medium size class contains a much larger proportion of tenanted area compared to any oilier size class, generalized land resumption has a greater impact on medium size class then on the small size class. Consequently, when size distribution of farms (and farm are) at different points in tune (1960, 1972 and 1980) are compared, the underlying process of land resumption for owner cultivation on large farms manifests itself in the form of polarization. The process of polarization in the size distribution of farms is likely to affect labor demand in the following way: 104Annexure II 105 a) Labour requirements on different size classes of farms have proportions of hire labour because of differences in proportion organization. Thus, for example, small farms fulfill a lower proportion ob their labour requirement with hired labour compared to medium sized farms due to a relatively greater propensity of small farmers to use family labour. On the other hand, large farms while they use virtually no family labour have a greater propensity to replace human labour with machines over time in an attempt to establish greater control over the production process and reduce risk. An important reason for labour displacing mechanization on large farms is that with multiple cropping there has been both an increase in the frequency of peak season demand For labour as well as a constriction in the time period available for performing labour operations at peak season. As a result of the latter, for a given quantity of labour a larger number of labourers are required. This generates two types of pressures on the Farmer to mechanize: (I) due to imperfections in the labour market the fanner often finds it difficult to hire a large number of labourers quickly, (ii) the Farmer faces an acute supervision problem due to the difficulty of mobilizing a large number of labourers to perform work tasks to his satisfaction. During my field visits I found that the persistent explanation of large farmers for mechanization ion was not so much “high” wages of farm labour but the difficulty of getting hold of them in lime and then ensuring that they get the job done “satisfactorily”. b) Polarization in the size distribution of farms could affect employment also because differing man days per acre are required on farms of different sizes. This effect will occur to the extent that there are differences between size classes of farms with respect to: (i) the percentage of cropped area devoted to crops with relatively higher labour requirement in each agri- 105106 Annexure II climatic zone, (ii) cropping intensities, and (iii) crop yields per acre. Micro survey data suggests that in some regions of the Punjab the above-mentioned factors result in a lower man (lays per acre requirement at either end of the farm size scale that in the medium size class. It appears then, that given the propensity of small farmers to use family labour rather than hired labour, and given the tendency of the large farmer to adopt labour displacing mechanization, a polarization in the size distribution of Farms is likely to dampen the growth rate in the demand for hi red labour. Moreover, in some regions variation across size classes in cropping patterns, cropping intensities and yields per acre may be such as to further reinforce this dampening in the growth of labour demand resulting from the polarization phenomenon. V.2 The Inverse Switching Hypothesis In Pakistan’s agriculture there is an overall supply of employable labour in excess of labour requirements in terms of cropped acreage under each crop under existing technologies. Yet, at the same time, localized labour shortages are observed during peak seasons in certain areas: The obvious reason for this paradox could be the bunching of demand for labourers at peak seasons in a situation of imperfect labour mobility. The imperfect labour mobility could be due to inadequate information available to the labour regarding the precise time and place of job availability on the one hand and poor transport facilities with in the rural sector on the other. Yet, here could be a more complex set of interactive factors, which may he accentuating the paradox of localized labour shortages within an overall situation of excess supply. These factors may he located in the changing composition of the agricultural labour Force with increasing weight of tenants seeking supplementary wage labour relative to pure landless labourers. At the same time landowners may be responding by adjusting systems of production organization, which 106Annexure II 107 involve tied labour supply. These interactive Factors may be leading to what one can call INVERSE SWITCHING of production technique in Pakistan’s agriculture: i. Landowners may refrain from complete resumption of rented out land and hence from moving into a “fully capitalist” labour process in an attempt to keep tenants as a source of tied labour. ii. At the same time. l who may be experiencing “spurious” labour shortages in proximate areas due to reduced labour mobility resulting from (I) above, may be mechanizing munch Faster than is warranted by the overall supply of employable labour. The combined died of (i) -and (ii) would be that for a given level of labour demand in terms of in an (lays/year) there would be a lowering of demand for permanent hired labourers, thereby creating a push factor for pure landless labourers to move into the cities looking for jobs. As the pure landless labourers migrate into towns there would be a further change in the composition of the agricultural labour force towards tenant-labourers. (i.e tenants who seek wage employment as a source of supplementary income.) This changing composition of the agricultural labour to force would serve to further intensity tendencies (i) and (ii) above. While considerable research based on new surveys would be required before we can accept or reject the inverse switching hypothesis. Yet, there is some indirect data available to illustrate that such a hypothesis is worthy of being tested systematically. In a survey of the homeless population of Lahore city. conducted in October 1987, we discovered that of the in rat migrants who had moved into Lahore less than two years ago. a much larger proportion were landless labourers, Compared to those who had migrated to Lahore city over 10 years ago10. An important study11 by Noman Majid based on a Field survey in rural Sind offers illustrative evidence that while a situation of excess labour supply exists at the provincial level, there could possibly be labour shortages in the peak months of November and April at a more regionally disaggregated level. For example, Majid’s estimates of the 107108 Annexure II annual labour time available with the employable population of each district of Sind was greater than his estimate for the total tasks completion time requirement for the year as a whole. Yet, when tasks completion time requirement disaggregated to the district level, Majid interestingly enough found that in 6 out of 14 districts of Sind the task completion time requirement was in excess of 30 days, given the employable labour force available. These districts where a labour shortage at peak season could occur are Badin. Sanghar, Khairpur, Shikarpur. Larkana and Jacobabad. It is interesting that when the districts of Sind are ranked according to Road Density, three of these (list rids (B ad in, Shikarpur, Jacobabad) have a rank at the lower end of the scale. This indicates that high labour demand at peak season in a situation of poor transport facilities, could create localized labour shortages. Majid suggests that there may be a tendency for landowners to simultaneously overcome the risk of peak season labour shortage and high wage rates (in case of employing permanent hi red labour).12 This optimization strategy is manifested in the retention of some part of their land by landowners who are engaged -in owner- cultivation on part of their land. This allows a source of tied labour supply, which can be hired ii and when required. The field survey evidence of Majid indicated that amongst landowners reporting owner-cultivation in the ownership size class of over 1000 acres, 80 percent of the landowners have rented out as much as 50 percent of their owned areas to tenants.13 At the same lime, their field survey data suggests that landowners may be adjusting their tenancy contacts to enable the landlord to take crucial decisions regarding production and marketing. For example, 88 percent of the landlords in their sample were taking input decisions, 83 percent were taking crop decisions, and 100 percent were marketing the cash crop of their tenant farm.14 The survey evidence of Majid suggests that the joint system of product ion organization (i.e., owner—cultivation combined with tenancy) allows the landlord the advantage of a tied labour supply while also enabling him to determine key 108Annexure II 109 management decisions on the tenant farm. Consequently, a “pre-capitalist” from of production organization may not switch into a specifically capitalist form, because the former has been restructured in the service of capital accumulation. VI. RECOMMENDATIONS This study has so far shown that given the expected increase of Pakistan population by another 30 million people over the next II years, and given the prohibitive cost of population absorption in the urban sector, tapping the potential for labour absorption in the rural sector has become an urgent policy imperative. My estimates of the maximum labour absorptive capacity in the crop sector over the next II years indicate that only about 8 million people can additionally be absorbed in this sector. Consequently, policy measures will have to l on utilizing the labour absorption potential of the non-crop sector in the rural areas. In this regard the following measures could be considered: VI. I Policy Direction 1. Development of infrastructure in small (owns for accelerating the development of Small—Scale Industries (SSI). Small—Scale industries could be linked with the agriculture sector on the one hand and large—scale manufacturing sector in the urban areas on the o as indicated in recommendations specified below. 2. Linkage of SSI with agriculture could be done by: a) Encouraging the establishment of milk collection and cooling centres which could provide additional cash income to farmers who own livestock and also generate employment. b) Fruits and vegetables are currently marketed with large differentials between farm and retail prices. Cold storage facilities together with marketing infrastructure could be established through village development councils, supported by district level professional expertise and credit. Availability of cold storage and marketing facilities for the farmers would also induce them to invest in these labour intensive crops. 109110 Annexure II c) Choice of appropriate technology in rice mills can also generate off farm employment. For example, a large number of two tons per hour labour intensive mills could be set up instead of a small number of the large 15 tons per hour capital intensive ones. d) Manufacture of farm-implements, and tractor repair and maintenance facilities. The institutional mechanism required to provide credit, training and special fabrication facilities is discussed in the following section on “Institutional Framework” 3. The linkage of SSI with large-scale manufacturing industries in the large towns close by needs to be established through a system of manufacture of components on a subcontract basis. Here again the institutional framework for ensuring quality control, delivery dates and provision of orders for components, and credit becomes important. (This is discussed subsequently.) 4. Development of livestock and social forestry, and fruit orchards together with food processing facilities in small towns. 5. Construction of rural infrastructure, especially water management and lining of canals to improve both delivery and application efficiencies of the irrigation system. VI.2 Institutional Framework 1. The institutional framework that could be considered for realizing the yield potential for the small farm sector in agriculture, as well as realizing the income employment potential of the off-farm sector, is the csta6lishmènt of multifunctional grassroots organizations of farmers at the village level. These village level organizations could be linked at the district level, through Support Institutions. The function of these Support Institutions would be to provide credit, technical expertise in project formulation, specification and overcoming bottlenecks to project implementation at the village level; and finally, provision of support in marketing and technical training of personnel. Example of successful grassroots experiments abound in South Asia. Some of the 110Annexure II 111 more prominent ones being the AKRSP in Gilgit and Skardu, the Orangi Project in Karachi. Bhoomi Sena in India, Comilla and the Grameen Bank in Bengal etc. The idea in Pakistan’s context is to provide a hack-up support mechanism for the rapid development and replication of such grassroots initiative 2. The institution for accelerating the growth of SSI in small towns and linking them with Large-Scale Manufacturing enterprises could be based in the district headquarters and have (he following functions: a) Arranging of sub-contracts from LSM for manufacture of parts and components to SSI. b) Conduct quality control and pinpoint/resolve bottlenecks in the SS1 to the fulfillment of their production schedules. These bottlenecks could be financial (credit for machines or working capital), technical (training of personnel) or managerial. c) Provide common facilities (at a price) such as heat treatment, forging and product design to SS I which normally does not have the financial and technical capacity for these operations. VII. OPERATIONALIZING RURAL INDUSTRIALIZATION VII.l The Task The latest survey of small-scale manufacturing establishments in Pakistan shows that there were a total of 24 I * 896 small manufacturing establishments in Pakistan which were employing 555,497 persons (see Table 4). The growth rate of manufacturing units over the period 1976/77 to 1983/84 was 5.58 percent while the growth rate of value added in this sector was faster at 8.16 percent. This indicates that over time (he composition of SSI has been changing positively in favour of higher value added units. As Table 5 shows, while the capital cost per employed person in the large—scale manufacturing (LSM) is substantially higher than in SSI, the productivity of investment (value added per unit of investment) in LSM is substantially lower than in SSI. It is the growth of SSI that needs to be not only accelerated substantially but also needs to be induced towards 111112 Annexure II a geographic disposition that results in the emergence of SS based growth nodes in the small towns of Pakistan. Such a process would enable a geographically diversified growth, that is relatively cheap in terms of infrastructural investment and also oriented towards employment generation. These growth nodes of SSI in small towns should be linked with the agriculture sector (producing farm implements and food processing) on the one hand, and with the Large-Scale Manufacturing Sector in large cities (through sub-contracting of components manufacture) on the other. Such forward and backward linkages would enable both an increase in agricultural productivity and also a reduction in the import costs of the large-scale manufacturing sector. This policy does not mean that SSI should grow at the expense of the LSM. In fact, establishing a heavy industrial base that imparts to Pakistan an indigenous technological change capability is essential for a self-sustaining and autonomous industrialization drive. The functions of rapid growth of SSI would be four food. (i) to help achieve the employment objective. (ii) to enable a regionally balanced industrial growth with relatively low infrastructural investment, (iii) to reduce the foreign exchange costs of large—scale industry, and (iv) to increase Value added and productivity in the rural sector. VII.2 Constraints to the Rapid Growth of SSI’s Field visits to a large number of SSI units in the Punjab and NWFP have revealed that while potential in many cases may he high, the units are producing low value added items like steel shutters or car exhaust pipes, instead of components for LSM, or high quality farm implements. This results in low probability, low savings and slow growth. There are the following major constraints to accelerating growth of SSI’S in small towns: 1. Inability of small units to get orders for components manufacture from LSM and farm implements from agriculture. 2. Inability to achieve quality control, and to meet tight delivery schedules. 112Annexure II 113 3. Lack of specific skills like advanced millwork, metal fabrication, precision welding, all of which are needed for producing quality products with low tolerances and precise dimensional control. In other cases accounting and management skills may be inadequate. 4. Difficulty faced by small units in getting good quality raw materials, which often can only be ordered in bulk (for which the small entrepreneurs do not have the working capital), and from far away large cities. 5. Lack of specialized equipment. 6. Absence of fabrication facilities such as forging, heat treatment and surface treatment which are required for manufacture of high value added products, but are too expensive for any one small unit to set up. 7. Lack of capital for investment and absence of credit facilities. VII.3 Overcoming the Constraints: Industrial Support Centres (ISC’s) The concept of the industrial support Centres is based on the fact that small-scale industrialists in Pakistan have already demonstrated a high degree of entrepreneurship, flexibility, innovation and ability to work hard. The ISC would provide an opportunity for rapid growth to SSI through local participation in extension services, prototype development, and diffusion of improved technologies, equipment and management procedures. The ISC would constitute a decentralized system which ensures continuous easy access to a comprehensive package of support services such as credit, skill training, managerial advice and technical assistance. The JSC would also be linked up with national research centres, and donor agencies for drawing upon technical expertise and financial resources of these agencies in the service of SSI. The ISC would he located in specified growth nodes where there exists a potential for major rural industrialization activities. The Industrial Support Centres would have the following functional dimensions: 113114 Annexure II (a) Marketing Provision of orders from the large-scale manufacturing sector for components and from farmers for farm implements. These orders would then the sub-contracted to the cluster of SSI units that the ISC is supposed to serve. The individual order would be sub-contracted to the SSI on the basis of the skills and potential strengths of the unit concerned. (b) Monitoring and Quality Control Having given the sub-contract, the ISC would then monitor the units closely and help pinpoint and overcome unit specific bottlenecks to the timely delivery and quality control of the manufactured products. These bottlenecks may be specialized skills, equipment, good quality raw material or credit. (c) Skill Training and Product Development The ISC would provide specialized supplementary skill training on its premises to workers in the satellite SSI units when required. At the same time, it would provide advice on jigs, fixtures, special tools and product development where required. (d) Forging and heat Treatment Facilities The ISC’s would establish at their premises plants for forging, heat treatment and surface treatment The SSI units could come to the ISC to gel such fabrication done on the products they are manufacturing on sub-contract, and pay a mutually agreed price for this jot) to the ISC. (e) Credit The ISC would provide credit to the SSI’s for purchase of new equipment and raw materials. In cases where raw materials are available in bulk supply, the ISC could buy it from the source, stock it on its premises and sell at a 114Annexure II 115 reasonable price to units as and when they need the raw materials. VII.4 Specific Technical Facilities at ISC’s The specific Facilities that could be available at ISC’s to fulfill their technology diffusion/fabrication functions are: 1. Materials testing laboratory. 2. Foundry. 3. Surface Treatment Plant (a) Hot Dip Galvanizing Unit. (b) Paint Spray Installation. 4. Welding Workshop. 5. Sheet Metal Unit: (a) This metal sheet and pipe bending unit. (b) Thick metal sheet unit. 6. Heat Treatment Unit. 7. Tool and Die-making Shop. 8. Automotive Workshop/Garage. 9. Design and Information Centre. VlI.5 Product Groups The product groups for which above facilities could provide support to SSI’s are: i) Agriculture The ISC’s could provide manufacturing support and marketing for SSI’s in the following products: a) Tools for manual work such as hoes, shovels, rakes. b) Animal traction equipment. lnspite of rapid tractorization in Pakistan there remains a high demand for ox-drawn implements. The main technology here is the assembly of section irons and plates. Forging is essential in this field but there is also need for cast iron. The production of this equipment may consist of: - Ploughs: (forging and structural sleet work). - Rotary—blade harrows (forging, casting and structural sled work). 115116 Annexure II - Bearings and other parts for animal drawn earls. ii) Power Traction Popular tractor drawn equipment contains cast as well as forged and mechanized parts. Welding is often necessary. Items to be produced my include: - Spare parts for power cultivators (mainly Forging): - Ground graders (mainly plate assembly): - Rollers (mainly plate assembly); - Seeders, ha and cultivators (plate stamping, casting and structural sleet work): - Components lo sprayers (aluminum casting) iii) Irrigation This equipment includes values and pumps (or industrial and household use. More complex technologies are involved in producing irrigation equipment. Among the technologies are the casting of non-ferrous metals and production of special cast iron. Typical products are: - Components for centrifugal pumps (all ICS workshop technologies are involved); - Connect ions and bends (mainly aluminum technologies): - Components for hand pumps (casting. machining and welding); - Components for sprayers (casting and machining): - Panels for water reservoirs and roof tanks (welding and sheet metal technologies). iv) Off-Road Transportation Off- road transport at ion includes rail transportation. Products are: - Parts for railway cars and rail transport (forging, castings, plate); - Bushings and covers (nodular cast iron); 116Annexure II 117 - Traction components (forged or shaped metalwork); - Brake components (cast iron): - Hooks, turnbuckles, clamps and other fastenings (mainly Forged). v) Vehicle Components Industry Vehicle components include spare parts for motorcars, trucks, buses, tractors and industrial conveying and hoisting equipment. Particular vehicle components subject to frequent breakdown, such as pulley systems, fans and traction hooks, should be considered. The following are representative items: - Brake discs and drums (pig iron); - Oil-tight covers, oil pumps, pistons (aluminum alloys); - Fans (aluminum alloy and Stamped plate); - Lights and tool kits (aluminum alloy and stamped plate): - Trolley reefing (stamped plate and structural steel work); - Hubs for tractor an(l trolley wheels (cast iron): vi) Metalworking The metalworking industries require metal containers, conveyors, gears, pulleys, electric motors castings, and supplies for trucks and cars. Typical products are: Plate bins (shaped plates); - Plate bins (shaped plates); - Components for rolling conveyors (plate or cast iron castings); - Pulleys and gears (iron castings and forging); - Equipment for ingots moulds (iron castings); - Blacksmith or smelter equipment (uses all ISC technologies); - Miscellaneous tools (mostly forged). - vii) Food and Related Industry The food processing industry in NWFP is still in its infant stage. However, the scope for the production of canned fruit, fruit juices and vegetables is quite favourable. The set- 117118 Annexure II up of such industries requires an approach on a case-to-case basis. Among the products are: - Containers for food liquids (normally stainlessSteel stamped parts); - Stainless steel vats, tables, containers for foodprocessing plants: - Wire products (b shelves, dish drainers); - Metal hanging panels; - Cookers, water heaters, solar heaters; - Components for seed-oil presses; viii) Construction Building yard machines are generally imported in whole or in pail from abroad. Domestic production of simple castings may partly replace imports. The following are construction products: - Building yard equipment (mostly forging); - Scaffolding material (mostly forging); - Mason tools (mostly forging); - Components for building yard machines; - Implements for rolling shutters or window screening (shaped plate, welding); - Components for door framing and windows (cast or stamped plate): - Drain covers, grates, road drain wells (cast iron); - Piping elbows and unions for (trains (cast iron); - Components For valves, gate valves, unions, portable or street and road signs. road fencing; - Hinges and locks. ix) Household Appliances Household appliance products for the model workshops are: - Bath tubs, showers and sanitary equipment (mostly cast iron); - Taps (non-ferrous casting); - Miscellaneous household fixtures and equipment (cast iron and alum in i urn castings and shaped sheets): 118Annexure II 119 - Brassware for fittings, stop cocks, water laps. x) Power and Telephone Line Fittings – Considering the ambitious plans in Pakistan for the increase in installed power capacity and electrification of rural areas, items in this category should be subject to market surveys and, if feasible, then produced. Possible ISC workshop items are: - Connection support and mooring clamps for power liens (cast iron and aluminum castings); - Accessories for overhead line supports (aluminum castings and forging); - Cable connection boxes (cast iron and aluminum castings); - Waterproof feeder boxes (cast iron and aluminum castings). xi) Valves for industrial Use Valves for industrial use include products that are almost exclusively nodular cast iron. Components include those of gate valves and fittings for gas and oil pipeline. Also included are components of small rotary compressors and radical fans which mostly use shaped-plate castings. Cast-iron pipes, centrifugally or statically cast, must also be considered. VII.6 Growth Nodes for Rural Industrialization The proposed growth nodes for rural industrialization where the new industrial Support Centres (ISC’s) could be located are as follows: 119120 Annexure II 120

No comments:

Post a Comment