Introduction
This section examines the crisis of State power that faces a number of South
Asian countries today and the problems and prospects of regional cooperation.
The crisis had been sparked by a process of imitative economic growth that
generated acute inequalities between regions and social groups; and a centralized
political process in which significant sections of the people are denied
participation in the decisions that affect their existence. Centralized political
power even where it is associated with a representative democratic system in
some areas takes the form of tyrannizing minorities. Alternatively, where the
democratic process is weak, centralized political power is wielded by a militarybureaucratic
oligarchy against the interests of the majority of the people. The
resultant upheavals have polarized the polity along ethnic, religious or regional
lines. State structures in which immature elites arc equipped with powerful
coercive forces, have responded to these upheavals not from the perspective of
strengthening fragile democratic structures, but from the narrow imperatives of
regime survival, Consequently, the use of coercive force against the dissident
social groups and the cynical political manipulation of religious/ ethnic emotion
by the ruling elite has only deepened the crisis. The tendency of growing
militarization and the fragmentation of society along ethnic, linguistic or
religious lines, creates the internal conditions for external Intervention. The crisis
of the State thereby assumes an international dimension and inhibits bringing out
the full potential of regional Cooperation, which can reinforce both sustainable
development and democracy.
The paper by Akmal Hussain examines these issues in historical perspective,
with reference to Pakistan. The paper by Gunasinghe and Sivathamby on Sri
Lanka examines the class character of the current conflict and indicates the
elements of a nonviolent solution. The recent lndo Sri-lanka accord may give the
Impression that the alternative articulated in this paper now has a merely
academic character, Yet the violent events following the arrival of Indian troops
in Sri Lanka, testify to the continued relevance of the nonviolent solution
proposed in this paper. The question arises: Is there an alternative to the gradual
undermining of the democratic potential in South Asia? Harsh Sethi in his paper
attempts to answer this question by examining the possible creative responses to
existing political trends in India. If the political alternative of building a viable
democratic polity is to be actualized, it must be located in the culture of the
people. The question then arises, are there elements in the cultural tradition of
South Asia, which could constitute the ideological basis of the political
alternative which is now on the historical agenda of South Asia?
The paper by Gowrie Ponniah examines the elements of a vital personality rooted
in the collective historical experience of the people, with special 198
reference to the female image. Akhar S Ahmed examines the potential in folk
consciousness of Islam as a made of containing ethnic conflict within the
dialectic of unity in diversity. These two papers bring out the importance of
culture in the process of building democratic states in South Asia. Ashis Nandy
examines political culture with reference to the image of decontrolled State
power. At the end of Part II. Pran Chopra considers the history of the attempts at
regional cooperation, and shows how the inherent asymmetry of the region can
possibly function in favor of developing a stake in regional cooperation among
the countries of South Asia. Q K Ahmad takes a critical look at the future
prospects of the first intergovernmental initiative at regional cooperation in South
Asia: SAARC, and sets out some elements the future research agenda for a
sustainable SARC. 199
8. The Crisis of State Power in Pakistan:
Militarization and Dependence*
AKMAL HUSSAIN
INTRODUCTION
South Asian States are today undergoing a severe crisis. The process of economic
growth which was supposed to create the material basis of a national identity is
beginning to undermine it: Although the growth of GNP in most cases has been
impressive, it has created increasing affluence for the few, while leaving a
substantial proportion of the population in acute poverty. At the same time, the
level of domestic savings has continued to remain at such a low level in a number
of South Asian countries that economic growth has been accompanied by
increased t on foreign loans, while the conditions attached to such loans have
begun to constrain the ability for independent economic planning. In the political
sphere, there is an increasing polarization between social classes and there are
growing tensions based on ethnic and regional hues. ‘the armed forces which
were supposed to he the guardians of geographic boundaries, arc increasingly
being used as coercive instruments against sub nationalist movements, and in
many cases the military—bureaucratic oligarchy is dominating political
Institutions rather than being subordinate to them.
In this paper we will attempt to examine these stresses on State and civil Society
in Pakistan in terms of the interplay between political and economic forces in a
historical perspective. Part 1 of the paper analyzes the nature and genesis of the
Pakistan movement and shows how thus conditioned the political and State
structure at the dawn of independence. Part II investigates the dominance of the
State apparatus over the political process. Here we focus on the changing social
origins and ideology of the army. Finally, in Part Ill we analyze the nature of
economic dependence and the growing militarization of civil society— a process
whose trajectory brings the power of the State into a potential confrontation with
the power of the People.
* Parts of this paper have appeared in au earlier Version titled ‘Pakistan, the crisis of
the State,’ in Asghar Khan (ed.) Islam, Politics and the State (London: Zed Press, 1985). 200
PART 1
THE NATURE AND ORIGINS OF THE PAKISTAN MOVEMENT
In considering the nature and origins of the Pakistan Movement, one comes
across two kinds of equally simplistic views at opposite ends of the indo-logical
spectrum. At one end, there is the metaphysical view of Muslim communal
‘historians’, who confine the concepts of cult in e and hut 1 strictly within the
bounds of religion. In this view Pakistan is seen as historical inevitability rooted
iii the doctrinal differences between Islam and Hinduism. At the other end of the
spectrum, there is the view that
The origin of the demand for Pakistan can he located in the dynamic interaction
of three political forces within India during the period from 1857 to 1940:
1. The British imperial government, which, it can be argued was interested
in undermining the gathering momentum of the national liberation
movement by accentuating its internal contradictions.
2. The Congress, representing the interests of an Indian national
bourgeoisie, which was essentially underdeveloped and that backpacked
genuine secularism in its political choices and language. Consequently,
the Congress was susceptible to communalist pressures, thereby
increasingly alienating the Muslim trading elite from the Indian
bourgeoisie.
3. The Muslim trading elite, which could he regarded as a nascent fraction
of the Indian bourgeoisie, was even less mature than its Hindu
counterpart. Due to its acute weak ness, in its rivalry with the more
powerful Hindu fraction, the Muslim ‘bourgeoisie’ was induced to seek
support from Muslim landlords and the colonial State on the one hand,
and reliance on an explicitly religious ideology on the other.
THE EMERGING MUSLIM ‘BOURGEOISIE’, THE BRITISH
AND THE NATIONAL MOVEMENT 1857—1928
One of the earliest attempts at articulating the political and economical interests
of propertied Muslims in British India can be traced to the Muslims educational
movements of Syed Ahmed Khan. His political ideas during the 1850s expressed
the interests of the rising Muslim ‘bourgeoisie’ and the 201
smaller landlords, who resented the feudal system in India and wished to receive
economic concessions from the British authorities. Thus, Syed Ahmed Khan
opposed the 1857 War of Independence as an attempt to restore the old feudal
nobility and supported the British on this issue. While being a staunch loyalist of
the British raj he urged industrial and commercial development and argued for
administrative reforms whereby Indians could be given a place in the country’s
administration.1
He called upon Muslims to educate themselves and to be
receptive to modern scientific ideas. In the pursuit of this objective he founded a’
scientific society in 1864. In 1877, helped by the British, Syed Ahmed Khan
founded the Muslim College at Aligarh. This institution sought to inculcate
loyalty to the raj in Muslims and at the same time became an influential political
and ideological center of Muslim propertied classes. Aligarh College made an
important contribution in producing a corpus of literature and a Muslim separatist
consciousness, which were vital to the subsequent emergence of a Muslim
political party in India.
The correspondence between the interests of the British m and the political
efforts of Syed Ahmed Khan can be, from his complete change in posture in the
period before and after the formation of the Indian National Congress in 1885.
Until I 88.S, he was a champion of Hindu—Muslim Unity and conceived of
Hindus and Muslims as part of the same nation: ‘Do not forget that Hindu and
Muslim are names referring to the religious denomination, but whether Hindu.
Muslim or Christian, so long as these people live in our country, they form one
nation regardless of their faith.
The formation of the Indian National Congress in 1885 was an at tempt by Indian
nationalists to challenge the political status quo and pressurize the British
authorities for reforms and self—rule. l though in the early Pl of the Congress
this struggle was conducted strictly within the structure of the colonial State,
Syed Ahmed Khan and the Muslim propertied interests whom he represented
strongly opposed the Congress struggle. Syed Ahmed Khan, who only a few
years earlier had championed Hindu—Muslim unity within a single nation, now
made an equally passionate attack on the Concept of composite Indian
nationalism. In a speech at Luck now on December 28, 1887, he remarked:
Now suppose that all the English were to leave India—then who would the rulers
of India Is it possible that under these circumstances two nations, Mohammedan
and Hindu, could sit on the same throne and remain equal in power? Most
certainly not. It is necessary that one of them should conquer the other and thrust
it down. lo hope that both could remain equal is to desire the impossible and
inconceivable (emphasis added).3
1
Syed Ahmed Khan, Asbab-i-Baghavat-i-Hind, cited in Y B Gankovsky and L R Gordon
Polonskaya, A History of Pakistan 1947-48 (Lahore: People’s Publishing, n.d.), p. 14.
2
A Akhtar, ed., Muzamin-I Sir Syed cited in Gankovsky and Polonskaya, supra, p. 16,.
3Speech by Syed Ahmed Khan, The Times (London), January 16, 1888. 202
The sharp change in Syed Ahmed Khan’s position on the relationship between
religion and nationhood expressed the imperative operating upon the infant
Muslim bourgeoisie. The bourgeoisie of north—west India historically emerged
much later than the bourgeoisie operating In Bengal and Bombay. In the latter
regions, because of their proximity to the sea, the pattern of expansion of the
colonial economy brought to them commercial and industrial activity much
earlier than in northern India, where the production of cash crops remained the
predominant function of the colonial economy. Consequently, the Muslim
bourgeoisie which originated in northwest India was much weaker than the
Hindu bourgeoisie, and in its Competitive struggle against the latter, it had to rely
on the support of M landlords and British authorities. Accordingly, as the
Congress emerged to threaten the interests of British metropolitan capital, the
weak Muslim fraction of the Indian bourgeoisie saw that in opposing the
Congress it could win concessions from the British.
Soon after the formation of the Congress, a Hindu movement against cow
slaughter, which provoked Hindu-Muslim riots, arose as part of a movement for
the purity of Hinduism.5
The Congress then declared that it was an all-India
organization representing both Hindus and Muslims. However, the Indian
national bourgeoisie was not fully developed, since it had emerged within the
highly restrictive structure of a dependent colonial economy. Its growth had not
occurred in the context of an economic and cultural conflict with feudalism, as in
the case. Consequently, the Indian national bourgeoisie had not transcended the
religious elements in its culture to achieve a secular political language. It was
therefore, not in a position to oppose effectively the anti—cow slaughter
movement. This failure led Syed Ahmed to brand the Congress a Hindu
organization and to argue that the Congress’ notion of self—rule would result in
Hindu dominance of India.
As the Congress gained organizational strength and enlarged its Social base, its
demand for a system of democratic representation of the Indian people began to
press the British authorities. It was at this stage that Aligarh College began to lay
an active role against the Congress by posing the fact of different religious
communities in India as an argument against a simple democratic representation,
in which the Hindus would have been in the majority.
4
Soon after the founding of the Congress, Syed Ahmed Khan organized the first a anticongress
organization of Muslim landlords and Intellectuals, called the United Friends of
India Society. As he said in a letter to his English friend, Graham, the purpose of this
society was to combat the politics of the Congress.
As the Congress Organization was formed, the newly appointed governor general of
India, Lord Dufferin, assisted by the British politician Allen Hume discussed with British
officials the chances of provoking anti-Congress disorders, in an attempt to undermine
the nationalist movement. A B Rajput, Muslim League Yesterday and Today, cited in
Gankovsky and Polonskaya, op. cit., p. 19.
5
Ibid, P. 18
6
The Lucknow speech was reported in The Times (London), January 16, 1888. 203
Te Indian national bourgeoisie, because of its low level of development had not
been able to achieve genuine secularism in its consciousness. It was therefore
susceptible to Hindu religious influence in both its political language as well as
occasionally its political choices. This was an important factor in fostering a
sense of insecurity about Congress intentions among the Muslim fraction of the
Indian bourgeoisie. The nascent Muslim bourgeoisie is relatively so much
weaker than its Hindu counterpart that it felt obliged to conduct its rivalry by
aligning itself with the British authorities and Muslim landlords and by using an
explicitly Muslim communal ideology in its anti-Congress rhetoric. This pushed
the Congress even further towards a Hindu direction. Thus, the veiled
communalism of the Congress and the open communalism of the Muslim
bourgeoisie fed off each other due to the underdeveloped nature of both lie Hindu
and Muslim fractions of Indian bourgeoisie. Whenever the nationalist movement
led by the Congress intensified, the doubts and misgivings between the Hindu
and Muslim communities were also accentuated. This psychological
characteristic of the relations between the Hindu and Muslim fractions of the
Indian bourgeoisie was reinforced by the political imperatives operating on the
British colonial regime, which aimed at intensifying communal conflict as a
device to weaken the nationalist movement, It is this particular interplay of forces
that explains the fact that at the high tide of the nationalist movement in 1905, the
Muslim League emerged as a separate political party of the Muslims.
The growing communalism in India (luring the first decade of the twentieth
century was not merely the result of British intrigue. The particular form of
political mobilization conducted by the Congress also accentuated the existing
distrust between the Hindu and Muslim communities. While the Congress was
formally a secular organization, in practice, its campaigns and political language
were characterized by Hindu symbolism. For example, during the 1905—11
campaign against the partition of Bengal, the Congress could have won the
support of most Muslim landlords since few Muslims Supported the division of
Bengal. Yet the Congress leaders alienated their Muslim supporters by using
Hindu anthems and Hindu symbols in their campaigns. Many Muslim
nationalists were outraged by this imagery and left the movement.
The Muslim middle classes in the competition for jobs felt at a disadvantage visa-vis
their Hindu counterparts. The Aligarh group. with the Support of the British
authorities, directed this tendency towards the demand for separate electorates
and an intensification of the communal issues.
Evidence of the British attempt at fomenting Hindu—Muslim communal tension
is provided by a private conversation between Mohsin—uI—Malik . and
7
Aligarh Institute Gazette, January 9, 1907, cited in Gankovsky and Polonskaya, op.
cit., p. 34.
8
Ibid., p. 27. 204
the Viceroy, Lord Minto. The Viceroy emphasized that Muslim political
activities should aim at achieving community representation for Muslims in order
to combat the political power of the Hindus; the viceroy further pointed out that
the British had high hopes for the loyalty of the Aligarh Group.9
The British policy of opposing the Hindu and Muslim communities finally found
a formal expression in the Indian Councils Act of 1909, which brought about
separate electorates for Hindus and Muslims.
MUSLIM LEAGUE AND THE DENOUEMENT
OF HINDU-MUSLIM CONFLICT: 1907—1947
The efforts of the Muslim landlords and Muslim commercial interests to form a
separate Muslim political party intensified in an environment characterized by
the Congress’ mass campaign for self-rule. This was increasingly couched in
Hindu mythological images, thereby generating a growing concern among the
bourgeoisie, landlords and middle class elements of the Muslim community.
The first specific proposal for a Muslim political association was made by Nawab
Salimullah of Dacca. He argued that such an association should support the
British administration, combat the mounting influence of the Congress and
protect Muslim communal interests.10 The essentials of Salimullah’s proposals
were accepted at a subsequent Dacca conference of Muslim leaders, chaired by
the well—known Aligarh figure, Viqar—uI— Malik ‘Ibis conference named the
new organization the All—Indian Muslim League.
The first conference of The All-India Muslim League opened in Karachi on
December 29, 1907. The founding fathers of the Muslim League belonged to the
Muslim groups of landlords and intellectuals from the Central and the United
Provinces, Bengal and the Punjab. The most influential group among them was
the Aligarh group. These were intellectual nawabs from established families who
had begun their careers in the Indian Civil Service in the United Provinces, later
supported Syed Ahmed’s educational Movement and finally devoted themselves
to Ahigarh College. Included among the founders of the Muslim league were a
few Muslim manufacturers, the most notable being Adamjee Pirbhai . The Aga
Khan (elected the first president of the League), apart from being head of the
Ismaili community, was closely connected to the Muslim manufacturers of
Bombay.
The resolution in the Dacca conference where the Muslim League was born
defined the following goals:
1. To promote among the Mussalmans of India feelings of loyalty to the
British Government and to remove any misconception that may arise as
to the intention of the government with regard to its measures.
9
Gankovsky and Poloskaya, , op. cit., p. 30.
10Ibid., p. 32. 205
2. To project and advance the political rights and interests of the
Mussalmans of India and to respectfully represent their needs and
aspirations to the Government.
3. To prevent the rise among the Mussalmans of India of any feeling of
hostility towards other communities without prejudice to the other
aforementioned objects of the League.11
Those few industrialists who had joined the Muslim League, while wanting to
use the pressure of the League to will concessions from the British, also wanted
the freedom to conduct business with the Hindu and Parsi communities. These
Muslim industrialists put pressure on the predominantly landlord leadership of
the League to adopt a less antagonistic attitude towards the Congress. It was this
influence of the industrialists that resulted in the League adopting the thirds point
of non-hostility towards other communities.
In 1908—10 the Muslim League established its main provincial bodies. These
were headed by big landlords and conservative Muslim intellectuals closely
associated with the landed elite. Thus , for example, tile Punjab League was led
by Shah din and Mian Mohammad Shafi; the East Bengal branch was headed by
Nizamuddin and Nawab Salimullah. The Muslim League leader from the United
provinces was Rajah Naushad Ali Khan (the biggest landlord of the region), and
in South India the Nizam of Hyderabad and other princes and landlords headed
the League. Only in Bombay, Bihar and Madras was League leadership in the
hands of members of the bourgeoisie.
By the eve of the First World War, big Muslim merchants had begun to invest in
industry. This generated a new dialectic of unity and rivalry between the Hindu
and Muslim fractions of the Indian bourgeoisie: On tile one hand, the developing
Muslim industrial bourgeoisie had an interest in strengthening and uniting the
struggle of the Indian bourgeoisie against the colonial regime, and, on the other,
as the Muslim commercial interests entered the domain of industry, their
contention with the established Hindu industrialists intensified.
Jinnah grasped this dialectic before any of the other League leaders and called for
united action by the Congress and the League for a constitutional Struggle for
self—rule. Mohammad Ali Jinnah was a well—known Bombay lawyer. Gifted
with an incisive intellect and fierce personal integrity, he was to emerge later as
the Quaid-i-Azam, the charismatic leader of the Muslim community. With his
vigorous constitutionalist approach to issues and liberal ideas, Jinnah in his early
political career was ideally suited as the champion of Hindu—Muslim unity.
During the First World War, Jinnah While still a member of tile Congress, rose to
become au influential leader of the Muslim League. Both the League and the
Congress accepted his idea for a Joint session of the two parties in Bombay in
December 1915. During this
11 Ibid., P. 34 206
session, while urging rapprochement with the Congress, Jinnah also proposed
that the agreement provide for the principle of special Muslim, representation in
the legislative bodies. The latter device was used, incorporate within the
agreement the tendency of rivalry with the Hindu hat prevailed among the
Muslim bourgeoisie and rising middle class.
The efforts bore fruit in the Lucknow Pact of I 916, which was endorsed by the
League and the Congress at their respective sessions. The pact envisaged that the
two parties would jointly struggle to established government bodies by direct
elections on the territorial principle, retaining die system of separate
representation for about ten years.
Between 1916 and 1920 there was a limited degree of cooperation between the
Congress and the Muslim League. However, strains began to appear when during
1918-—I 920 anti—British Muslim ulema mobilized Muslim masses for the
Khilafat movement and the Congress declared Support for it. Jinnah and his
group in the League disapproved of the Khilafat movement constitutional
grounds. Matter came to a head when at the end of 1920 the Congress launched a
mass civil disobedience movement, and Jinnah attacked the decision on tactical
grounds. He stated in a letter to Mahatma Gandhi that he would not support it,
Because the movement put the masses in motion and this would lead to chaos:
‘What the consequences of this nay be, I shudder to contemplate.’’ At the 1921
session of the Muslim League in Calcutta, Jinnah argued that Gandhi’s was the
wrong way. ‘Mine is the might way,’ lie declared. ‘The constitutional way is the
right way.’ The opposing positions adopted by Gandhi and Jinnah on the issue of
civil disobedience movement partly reflected the opposing political styles of the
two leaders.: Gandhi’s dramatic politics of the street as opposed to Jinnah’s
constitutional style of the legislative assembly. In any case, following
disagreement on the civil disobedience movement, Jinnah resigned from the
Congress In 1921 and the lukewarm Congress—League cooperation begun with
the Lucknow Pact in 1916 suffered a serious setback.
During the period 1923 to 1927 the frequency of communal riots between Hindus
and Muslims increased alarmingly, resulting in 450 dead and thousands injured.
To reduce the mounting communal tension, Gandhi and Muslim nationalists like
Abdul Kalam Azad initiated a move for a new ‘national pact’ between the
Congress and the Muslim League. Jinnah and the League responded favorably.
12H Bolitho, Jinnah: Creator of Pakistan (London: John Murray, 1954), p. 84.
13 While the civil disobedience movement was in progress, the Moplah revolt broke out
in 1921. This was essentially an uprising by the poor peasantry of Malabar against the
landlords. However, since the peasants were mainly Muslims and the landlords mostly
Hinds, the British press publicized it as a communal Hindu-Muslim war. The British
interpretation was questionable, since in many places poor Hindus joined the revolt.
Kunna Ahmad Haji, a peasant chief, wrote to Madras daily The Hind rebutting charges
of communalism and accusing the government of attacking Hindu temples to induce
discord between the communities. 207
In March 1927 at Delhi, there was a meeting of Muslim intellectuals who favored
a united movement for home rule by the Congress and Muslim League. During
this meeting a press statement was issued by the Muslim intellectuals declaring
that the principle of general elections to central and provincial legislative bodies
(as advocated by the Congress) was acceptable on the following conditions:
1. The establishment of Sind as a separate province.
2. Provincial self—government for NWFP and Baluchistan on an equal
footing with other province.
3. Seats for Muslims in the Punjab and Bengal provincial legislative bodies
in proportion to the Muslim population of these provinces.
4. Not less than one—third of the seats for Muslims in the central
legislatures.
This document, which became famous as the Delhi Manifesto, was drawn up by
Jinnah and Maulana Mohammad Ali and was the basis of a new, albeit transient,
understanding between the Muslim League and the Congress. The League
declared that it was prepared to disown the separate representation system on the
terms set out in the manifesto, a position it was to maintain until 1937. This was
an important concession. The Congress in its Madras session the same year also
declared approval of the Delhi Manifesto and called for an all-parties conference
to devise a new constitution.
These events appeared to indicate that a favorable situ for Hindu— Muslim unity
had arisen. Yet communal conflicts soon expressed them selves in the relations
between the Congress and the League, as indicated earlier. The Congress, in spite
of its secular ideology, was susceptible to Hindu communal influence in its
political language and its choices. The political position adopted by the Congress
at the All—Parties Conference was an important illustration of this fact. Under
pressure from the right-wing Hindu religious party called the Hindu Mahasabha,
the Congress leader ship in violation of its earlier stand rejected the basic points
of the Delhi Manifesto. Jinnah urged that the basic demand of the Delhi
Manifesto be Worked into the constitution being devised at the All-Parties
Conference in both Lucknow (June 1928) and Calcutta (December 1928).
Thoroughly disillusioned by the Congress, Jinnah declared after the abortive
Calcutta Conference: ‘This is the parting of the ways.14 History proved him right.
After the failure of the attempts at League-Congress cooperation in 1928, and
with the onset of the world economic crisis (1929—33), the prospects of growth
of the Muslim bourgeoisie in alliance with the Indian national bourgeoisie were
severely constricted. There was a growing awareness among the leaders of the
Muslim League that its political future lay across classes with all Muslims. This
required an ambitious political program with a
14 H. Bolitho, op. cit., p. 95.208
broad-based appeal. The first step towards this objective was the formula lion of
Jinnah’s fourteen points, after the All—Parties Muslim Conference in Delhi in
January 1929. The crucial feature of these fourteen points (later submitted to the
Round Table Conference in 1930) was the recognition of the regional diversity of
India and the need for provincial autonomy. Jinnnh demanded a federal
constitution with residuary powers vested in the provinces and a uniform
measure of autonomy for all provinces. Jinnah also demanded guarantees for the
free development of the vat ions national languages and the freedom of religion.
Jinnah’s fourteen points won the support of almost all the Muslim political
groups, including those which had taken part in the civil disobedience campaign.
This constituted the first step in enlarging the support of the Muslim League
among all Muslims.15
When the British government announced the Communal Award, the
fundamentals of the new constitution, the Muslim League initially supported it.
However, by the time the Government of India Act was published in 1935 the
campaign of the Congress against the new constitution had gained wide
popularity among the masses, including many Muslim peasants. Jinnah had the
sagacity to recognize that continued support for the constitution would preclude
possibility of the Muslim League gaining a mass following among the Muslims.
Accordingly, in its April 1936 session at Bombay, the Muslim League reversed
its earlier position and refused to approve the constitution of 1935. This was a
turning point in the history of the Muslim League, for it represented a recognition
by the Muslim League leadership of the need to gain the support of broad
sections of the Muslims of India.
The results of the 1937 elections showed that the Indian National Congress had
emerged as an all—India organization, capturing 716 out of 1585 seats and
qualifying to form ministries in six provinces.16 Al the same time the Congress
claim dial as a secular party it represented all communities was not borne out by
the election results, For the Congress failed to get a
The most important of the points affecting the interests of Muslims were as follows,:
1. The reservation of not less than one third of the seats in the central and
provincial cabinets for Muslims.
2. Granting Muslims an adequate share along with other Indians in all the services
Of the State and local self-governing bodies.
3. Solutions of communal questions to be subject to an affirmative vote of three
fourths of the community concerned.
4. Establishment of Sind province, which was to be separated from the Bombay
presidency.
5. Legislative bodies for NWFP and Blaluchistan
16 Z H Zaidi, ‘Aspects of the Development of Muslim League Policy 1937-47’ in C H
Philips and M D Waiwright (eds.), the Partition of India (London: George Allen and
Unwin, 1970), p. 253. 209
significant percentage of the Muslim vote, having won only twenty-six out of
total 482 seats reserved for Muslims (i.e. 5.4 percent). While the Muslim League
made a stronger showing compared to the Congress in the Muslim— reserved
seats, winning 109 seats out of 482 (i.e. 23 percent), it could not claim on the
basis of 23 percent of the Muslim reserved seats to he the representative of Indian
Muslims.17 What was perhaps even more worrying for the Muslim League was
that it was weakest in the Muslim-majority provinces. For example, the League
won only two seats in the Punjab (compared to the Unionists, who won 101 out
of 167 provincial assembly seats); in Sind and NWFP the Muslim League could
not win even a single seat.
The results of the 1937 elections brought home an important lesson to the
Muslim elite which led the League: If the Muslim League were to negotiate with
the British as a representative of Indian Muslims, then an effective party
organization in at least the Muslim—majority areas was of crucial importance.
Equally important was the need to articulate a new political program and new
slogans which could mobilize the emotional charge of broad sections of the
Muslim masses.
Soon after the elections the Muslim League, in its October 1937 session at
Lucknow, adopted a new constitution, The basis of this new constitution was the
‘two—nation theory’ and the demand for autonomy of Muslim— ma provinces
within a fully independent Indian federation. The new constitution catered to
poorer sect ions of Italian Muslims by opening its membership to all Muslims
regardless of class, reducing its membership fee to a nominal two annas per
month and envisaging a reduction in rent, relief from usury and a guaranteed
minimum wage for workers.
The demand for the autonomy of the ‘Muslin nation’ was accompanied by
campaigning for specifically Muslim chambers of commerce, industry and
similar organizations in the agriculture sector. ‘the Muslim League campaign of
focusing politics along the communal principle found expression in the first
session of the Sind branch of the Muslim League. At this Session (presided over
by Jinnah) there was a demand for the division of India into a federation of
Hindu and Muslim states.
‘the new constitution contributed to the increased influence of the Muslim
League among the Muslims of India, Another factor enhancing Support for the
League among Muslims was the deterioration of I Linda— Muslim relations as a
result of the mode of operation of the Congress provincial ministries. ‘the
Congress ministries, while ignoring the demands of Muslims, claimed to
represent the interests of Muslims as well as Hindus. What outraged the religious
feelings of the Muslims was that whereas legislation passed in provinces where
Congress governments were in power permitted songs and dances in front of
mosques, yet killing cows, which was against the religious beliefs of Hindus was
made a criminal offense. The
17 Imran Ali, Punjab Politics in the Decade Before Partition, Research Monograph
Series No. 8, South Asian Institute (Lahore: University of the Punjab, 1975), P. 1. 210
Suspicion among Muslims that the Congress had a Hindu communal orientation
was given further weight by the fact that Bande Mataram, a patriotic hymn
expressed in Hindu images, was declared the national anthem. The Congress
stand on the language issue also incensed many Muslim intellectuals. Hindi was
made compulsory in schools while the Congress refused to introduce the Urdu
language and Arabic and Persian literature even in regions where the traditional
Muslim community regarded these as the basis of Muslim education.
The susceptibility of the Congress to Hindu communal influences, together with
the appeal to Muslim communalist sentiment by the political c of the League,
intensified the polarization between the Hindu and Muslin communities. By the
time of the Second World War, the earlier demand of Muslim leaders for
autonomy of Muslim—majority provinces within an Indian began to be replaced
by the demand for secession of these provinces. The Working Committee of the
Muslim League, in the session of September I 7— 18, 1939, rejected the federal
objective on grounds that such a federation would ‘necessarily result in a
majority community rule’ and argued that this was totally unacceptable in a
country ‘which is composed of various nationalities and does not constitute a
national state.18
In December 1939, with the resignation of Congress ministries in NWFP Sind
and Assam, followed by anti-Congress riots in many provinces, communal
passions rose to a new pitch. As the momentum of communal conflict built up,
the Muslim League at its Lahore session on March, 23, 1940 made a historic
declaration. It was proclaimed that the Indian Muslims sought the division of
India on religious principles and the establishment of a Muslim State called
Pakistan.19 Subsequently, between 1940 and 1946, the Muslim League in its
negotiations with the Congress and the British authorities kept open the option of
a number of solutions short of the outright partition of India. However, by 1946
all other options were closed, and Pakistan came into being as an independent
state on August 14, 1947.
As Imran Ali in a well documented paper on the decade 1937-1947 has argued,
the growth of mass popularity of the League in this period was associated with
the growth of tension between the Hindu and Muslim communities. However, on
the regional level, ‘… the role of non-communal factors such as class, the
existing power structure … and internecine rivalries can by no means be
discounted.20 In the Punjab, the emergence of the League as a major political
force involved not only an exercise in the use of popular politics, but also an
accommodation with the Punjab national Unionist Part – the party of the big
feudal landlords of the Punjab. An important factor in the victory of the Muslim
League in the 1946 election.
18 Speeches and Documents on the Indian Constitution, 1921 – 1947, 2 Vols, (London,
1957), pp. 488-90, quoted in Gankovsky and Poloskaya, op. cit., p. 71.
19 Chaudhri Mohammad Ali, The Emergence of Pakistan (New York: Columbia
University Press, 1967), pp. 38-9.
20 Ibid., p. 48. 211
was that by then, through a combination of intimidation and conciliation the
Muslim League had Won over from the Unionist Party the most power full of the
Muslim feudal landlords of the Punjab.21 In the vital months that followed the
1946 elections up to August 1947, the Muslim League and the Pakistan
movement were controlled mainly by the Punjabi feudal elite. This phenomenon
led to the dominance of Pakistan’s power structure by the landlords of the Punjab
during the post-partition era.
It has been seen that the vicissitudes of Jinnnh’s attempts at achieving HinduMuslim
unity (1909-1928) expressed the contradictions of an emerging, Muslim
bourgeoisie, which was competing for a market against an established Hindu
bourgeoisie. These contradictions became antagonistic because they occurred in a
situation where the economic space for both was severely restrict ed by the
economic structure of a colonial regime and the predominance of metropolitan
capital. What gave these economic contradictions between two fraction of an
embryonic class an explosive political potential was a deep—rooted tension
between the Hindu and Muslim communities, which had ebbed and flowed with
the rise and fall of the Mughal empire. The process of the development of State
structures and ruling ideologies in India had not succeeded in creating the
institutions within which diverse communities of the subcontinent could evolve a
fundamentally unified identity.
PART II
THE DOMINANCE OF THE MILITARY-BUREAUCRATIC OLIGARCHY
The predominant position of the bureaucracy and the army in the structure of
State power in the newly formed country was due to the form of the freedom
struggle on the one hand and the nature of the Muslim League on the other. Since
the freedom struggle was essentially a constitutional one, the State apparatus of
the colonial regime remained largely intact at the time of independence. The
bureaucracy and the army, which constituted the ‘steel frame’ of the raj,
continued after the emergence of Pakistan to determine the parameters within
which political and economic changes were to occur. The predominance of the
bureaucracy an(l military in the exercise of State power in Pakistan was also due
to the fact that unlike the Indian National Congress, the Muslim League was
more a movement than a Political party. During the Pakistan movement it had not
been able to institutionalize its popular support in terms of a stable party
structure, a manifesto based on mass support for I lie solution of Pakistan’s
economic and political problems and a political culture which could ensure the
primacy of representative political government in the structure of State power.
The dominance of the Muslim League by retrogressive landlords had further
21 Punjab Legislative Debates 1936 and 1946, cited in Imran Ali, op. cit., p. 48.
22 For a more detailed analysis and documentation of this proposition see Imran Ali,
op.cit., pp., 7-54. 212
undermined the ability to create, in the new country, a political framework within
which popular aspirations could be realized.
At the time of independence, the principal protagonists in the exercise of State
power were the bureaucracy, the military, the big landlords and the nascent
bourgeoisie. Hamza Alavi in his pioneering work has argued that because of
colonial development the institutions of the army and bureaucracy are
‘overdeveloped’ relative to the ruling classes (the landlords, the indigenous
bourgeoisie arid the metropolitan bourgeoisie). Accordingly, tire militarybureaucratic
oligarchy has ‘relative autonomy’ within the State and is able to
intervene and mediate whenever the rivalry between the ruling classes becomes
so intense that it threatens the framework within which the rivalry is conducted:
I have argued that this relatively autonomous ‘overdevelopment of the, state in
such peripheral societies as Pakistan and its dominating presence in civil society
is related to the plurality of economically dominant classes in these societies,
namely metropolitan capital, the indigenous bourgeoisie, and landowning classes
whose rival interests and competing demands are mediated by the state. The post
colonial stat e which thus sits in judgment over them must enjoy a degree of
freedom vis a vis each of them individually, though collectively it must remain
subject to imperatives of the social order in which these rival classes are together
ensconced and the structural imperatives of peripheral capitalism.23 (Emphasis
mine).
The relative autonomy of the military—bureaucratic oligarchy and its ability to
perform a mediating function has been considerably undermined since the
seventies, The reason is that important changes have occurred since the sixties
within the military-bureaucratic oligarchy and hr its relationship to civil society.
The military—bureaucratic oligarchy in Pakistan was never a static monolith but
an institution whose internal social composition and relationship to society were
subject to change in the process of economic and social development. In the
immediate post-independence period the officers were predominantly from the
landowning class with an ideology derived essentially from the British military
traditions: Attitudes of professionalism and the need to insulate the armed forces
from the daily conduct of civil prevailed. However, during the mid-sixties and
seventies the social origin of the officer corps shifted towards the petit
bourgeoisie in the urban areas and in the countryside. This shift in the class
origins of the officer cot accompanied by increasing ideological factionalism in
terms of a mentalist religious ethos on the one hand and a liberal left-wing ethos
on the
23 Hamza Alvi, Class and State in Pakistan, in H Gardezi and J Rashid (ed.), Pakistan:
The Unstable State (Lahore: Vanguard, 1983). 213
other.24 The tendency towards the emergence of opposing political perspectives
within the officer corps was reinforced by two important develop- merits. First,
the right—wing Jamaat—i—lslami systematically sent its sympathizers and
many of its cadres to seek a commission in the armed forces; second, the radical
nationalist rhetoric of former Prime Minister Z A Bhutto and the rapid promotion
of officers who appeared committed to his regime also influenced the officer
corps.
The most important consequences of the opposing ideological trends within the
military was its politicization as an institution and thus the erosion of its ‘relative
autonomy’. To the extent that the military was politicized by opposing politic
forces operating outside it, the ability of the ‘military—bureaucratic oligarchy’ to
‘mediate’ between these opposing political forces was Undermined. Moreover,
the task of mediation was also made increasingly difficult as the regional
question gained importance in Pakistan, and the military began to be seen as the
representative of the interest of the ruling elite of the Punjab by the people of
other provinces of Pakistan.25
24 These ideological factions do not normally manifest themselves due to the rigid chain of
command in the military hierarchy and the stake of all officers in the integrity of the armed
forces as an institution. Nevertheless, the successful attempt at a coup d’etat in 1977 by what
later emerged as a religious fundamentalist military regime, and I he unsuccessful attempt by
younger officers against the regime in January 1984, are symptomatic of the differences in
ideological perspectives within the military.
25 In Pakistan, the military and the bureaucracy assumed control of State power soon alter
independence. Such dominance of the military—bureaucratic oligarchy was derived from the
structure of Slate power itself; moreover, political institutions and the dominance of
mobilizing political power were not developed enough to ensure the dominance of the popular
will. In contrast In the political institutions, the military-bureaucratic oligarchy which Pakistan
inherited from the colonial State was highly developed, and after independence it began to
reign supreme.
Muhammad Mi Jinnah, the first Governor General of Pakistan, was a man with a towering
personality and a democratic vision. However, at the dawn of independence he was too ill to
wield effective control of over the State (he died in September 1948, a year ill (of
independence), He was, therefore, unable to establish an institutional framework through
which the military and the bureaucracy could be subordinated to the political process.
Prime Minister Liaqat Ali Khan, Jinnah’s trusted assistant, lacked the initiative and
imagination to control the affairs of State effectively after Jinnah’s death. ‘the provincial
assemblies were elected on the basis of a limited franchise extending to only 15 percent of the
populace. Consequently, members of these assemblies and the cabinets which they elected
were aware of their isolation from the masses. They, therefore, willingly became instruments
of the military-bureaucratic oligarchy. ‘this conies out clearly in the events of 1953. In April
1953, the Governor General, Ghulam Mohammad, who was an 01(1 bureaucrat, dismissed the
Nazimuddin government even though the Constituent Assembly had given it a vote of
confidence. Soon after the dismissal of the Nazimuddin government by the Governor General,
the Constituent Assembly met again and passed another vote of confidence-this time in favour
of the new Prime Minister, Mohammad Ali Bogra, who had been nominated to the office by
the Governor General. Not only did the Governor General appoint the new Prime Minister,
but he also nominated ministers and assigned 214
THE SOCIOLOGY OF THE OFFICER CORPS
Indian officers in the British Indian Army were recruited from the landowning
class, though not necessarily from the aristocracy. As MacMunn, suggests, ‘the
staunch old Indian yeoman who came into the Indian commissioned ranks via the
rank and file of the Indian landowner of lesser class made the Indian officer as
we know him. 26
In the post—partition period in Pakistan, two factors have further integrated the
officer corps into the propertied class:
1. Since the Ayub era, the policy of giving land grants to senior army
officers has created a landed elite among even those officers who did not
come from large landowning families. This phenomenon has continued
to this date, with the addition that now many officers am being granted
land in urban estates.
2. Many army officers have been provided with opportunities of joining the
trading or industrial elite. A number of officers were given prestigious
places on hoards of companies after retirement, while for other contracts
and credits were arranged to help set up prosperous firms. Since 1977,
this tendency has appreciably intensified, ‘the appointment of army
officers as Chairmen of many public corporations in the nationalized
sector as well as WAPDA (Water and Power Development Authority)
and the N LC (National Logistics Cell) has increased the military’s
ability to grant lucrative contracts to officers operating private firms in
trade and industry.
Thus, an influential section of the army establishment is now closely integrated
with the landed and business classes of Pakistan.
According to Stephen Phillips Cohen, there have been three distinct generations
in the Pakistan officer crops:27
1. The ‘British’ generation: pre—1947.
2. The ‘American’ generation: 1953— l965.
3. The Pakistani generation: 19655 to date.
____________
them their respective portfolios. Thus, State power effectively passed into the hands of
the Governor General. The function of the Constituent Assembly was reduced merely to
rubber-stamping the actions of the Governor General and the military-bureaucratic
oligarchy whom he represented. Over the years, there have been some shifts in the
relative power exercised by each partner, hut what has remained is the complementarity
between these partners in the military-bureaucratic oligarchy. For a detailed discussion
oil this period, see II Alavi: The Military in the State of Pakistan. Sussex, 1974 (mimeo.)
26 Sir George MacMunn, The Martial Races of India (n.d.), p. 233 in Stephen P P
Cohen, Security Decision- in Pakistan, US Department of State. Office of External
Research (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1954).
27Stephen P Cohen, security Decision-making in Pakistan, op. cit. chapter 4. 215
It must be emphasized that each generation absorbed some of the characteristics
it inherited torn the earlier generation, through the culture embodied in the
process of training, promotion and daily social life of the office.
The British—trained officers who entered the Pakistan Army at the time of
partition Consisted of three distinct groups: but all three had served during the
1939—45 War. Two of these groups had entered the British Indian Army during
peacetime and received their training either at Sandhurst (e.g., Ayub Khan) or at
the Indian Military Academy at Dehra Dun (e.g., Mohammad Musa). The third
group of officers (the Indian Emergency Commissioned Officers) joined 1 British
Army during the Second World War (e.g., Mohammad Zia-ul-Iiaq). All the
prewar officers have retired, and only a few who entered during the Second
World War remain in the Pakistan Army today. However, the older officers left a
permanent impact on the culture and attitude of the officer corps, for they had
organized the main training and educational establishments after partition and
served as a model for the younger officers.
Officers who joined the British Indian Army on regular commissions before the
Second World War were carefully selected from prestigious or upper—middle
class families. A few were included front the ranks arid were generally the sons
of JCOs who had distinguished themselves in service. However, the same
rigorous criteria of selection did riot apply to officers who had joined during the
war through the Emergency Commissioned Officers scheme. The official British
analysis regarding such officers was that they were on the whole inferior to both
regular Indian commissioned Officers and their British Emergency
Commissioned officers equivalent.
Apart from the differing professional and attitudinal characteristics of the officers
who originated in the British Indian Army, there was another important
sociological characteristic. About 12 percent of the Muslim officers in the British
Indian Army were not from areas that later constituted Pakistan. Many Muslim
officers from Delhi, UP, Eastern Punjab and Central Provinces constituted an
important section of the senior ranks of the Pakistan army until recently. The
sons of these officers constitute an important fraction of the current officer corps.
These officers exercised the option of migrating from their home towns in India
and are especially charged with a Sense of communal feeling against the Hindus
and a sense of mission about living in an Islamic State. For example, one of the
most senior officers of the Pakistan army stated in an interview with Cohen:
I am a pure Rajput my family has been Muslim for only two or three generations.
But I felt that India had to he divided, and told Messervey (the first Commander
of the Pakistan Army) that I would rather live in a small country as a free man
than as a sweeper in a large country . . . I did not want to see i children serve
under Hindus.29
28Stephen P Cohen, The Indian Army (Berkeley: University of California, 1971), p. 145
29Stephen P. Cohen, Security Decision making in Pakistan, op. cit., p. 61. 216
Another Senior officer Who was ft lieutenant colonel in 1946, and who also
chose to leave his home for Pakistan, saw the new State as an opportunity to
build a society according to Islamic values:
I basically belong to India, Lucknow; all the people who belong to this halt of the
world (Pakistan) , they came here automatically We had the choice or option; but
I think more than anything else it was a desire to have a homeland of your own
where you could model it according t your own ideology, your own genius.30
With the establishment of Pakistan’s military relationship with the United State
in 1953, extensive changes took place in the Pakistan military establishment at
the level of organization and training. But perhaps even more important was the
Americanization of the ethos of the officer corps. This occurred essentially as the
result of two aspects of the American military aid program:
1. Hundreds of Pakistan army officers were sent to the United States m
specialized training. The mental attitudes that were inculcated during this
period and the ideological perspective adopted were then diffused within
the officer corps on their return.
2. An extensive motivation program was mounted by United States Army
personnel in Pakistan. This was done by creating a separate cell in the
Inter—Services Directorate and involved systematic indoctrination of the
Pakistan officer corps.
Evidence of the extensive organizational changes and of the Americanization of
the Pakistan army’s ethos is provided by a close associate of former President
Ayub Khan:
The changes brought in this army—few other armies went through such
extensive tremendous changes. The field formations, the schools, the
centers and even General Headquarters —every thing was changed. The
Americans affected everything—the scales were completely different,
hundreds of our officers went to America, and we had new standards of
comparison.31
The profound effect which the training of Pakistan army officers in the United
States had on their minds can be judged by the views of a young Pakistani
colonel who was trained with the United States Special Force.
…We were friends. I made many friends in the United States. Didn’t you know
we were the best friends and allies you had in the area, the
30Ibid.
31Ibid.. p. 72, 217
only dependable one? Why did you not realize that? Our two countries arc SO
much alike, we think alike, we like the same things....There could be a new
alliance to hold click the Russians.32
Perhaps the most effective penetration by United States Army personnel at the
ideological level was done by means of the motivation program conducted by a
special cell in the Inter-Services Public Relations Directorate. Cohen writes:
‘The US1S extended its operations in Pakistan under the so—called Motivation
(later Troop Information) Program. A separate cell was created in the (Pakistan)
Inter—Services P.R. Directorate to handle the collection and Distribution of
American journals, books and films throughout the Pakistan Army, Navy and Air
Force. The so—called Motivation Program was an elevation of normal P.R. to a
higher sphere of intellectual education and indoctrination. It funned an integral
part of the entire military aid program.33
This infiltration of the ideological and institutional structure of the Pakistan
military establishment by United Stated military personnel reached a stage where
the very national image of the armed forces was affected: The American military
presence somewhat compromised the purely national image of the armed forces
It seemed as ii there were two military establishments in one country: one
national, the other foreign.34
The foregoing analysis has indicated that close organizational and ideological
links between the Pakistan avid United States military establishment developed
during the period 1953 to 1965. Thus, in the very period in which the military—
bureaucratic oligarchy could be regarded as being ‘relatively autonomous’ from
the domestic ruling classes, we find that it had close structural connections with
the institutions of metropolitan capital.
The important characteristics of officers who have joined the Pakistan Army in
the last fifteen years arc as follows:
1. They are drawn much more from the middle classes than the land—
owning classes as in earlier years.
2. They have been subjected the least to direct foreign professional
influence and are the products of a purely domestic educational system.
Many such officers who joined in about 1971 are now majors or colonels. As
Eqbal Ahmed has suggested, this generation of officers with petit bourgeois
social origins and a purely indigenous socialization is highly
32Ibid., p. 73
33Ibid., p. 74
34Ibid., p. 75 218
susceptible to the fascist ideology of the Jamaat—i— Islami. This tendency may
be further reinforced by two factors:
1. The active attempt made by the Jamaat-i-Islami to penetrate the officer
corps with its own trained cadres on the one hand and to distribute its
literature in the military establishment on the other.
2. The new programme of sending combat office, s to universities in
Pakistan has subjected many officers to more systematic indoctrination
by the Jamaat , which dominates SO of the important universities of time
country.
POLITICIZATION OF TI It MILITARY
During the period after 1971 not only were the officer corps subjected to I he
indoctrination of the Jamaat—i—Islami hut they were also exposed to the
populist rhetoric of the Pakistan People’s Party. Many young officers with a
social conscience who were worried about the economic deprivation of the
masses and the crisis of the State saw in Bhutto time harbinger of a strong new
Pakistan. The nationalization of some Big industries, the melodramatic
handcuffing of Some of the biggest industrialists, and the radical rhetoric against
feudalism had an impact on not only the in middle peasants and urban
professional classes but also the new generation of army officers who originated
from these classes. That the army top brass itself is aware and concerned about
the influence of the Bhutto phenomenon on the minds of army officers is
indicated by a ‘player’ issued to all units by General Headquarters, Military
Intelligence Directorate, Rawalpindi in 1978-89:
‘God will provide men to the army who have strong minds, great hearts true fail
Ii and ready hands ...There is an implicit reference to the just executed Prime
Minister Bhutto: ‘men who can stand before a demagogue and damn his
treacherous flatteries wit bout winking.’
It appears that perhaps the fundamental feature of the ‘Pakistani generation’ of
officers is that they were politicized from both the left and the right wing of the
political forces in civil society. ‘this suggests that underlying the strict discipline
there may be potential or actual factionalism among the officers, which may
manifest itself if the armed forces as an institution at t used to crush a popular
political movement in Pakistan.
Jo the extent that politicization of the officer corps has occurred, the military may
have lost the ‘relative autonomy’ which could be regarded as the basis of its
ability to mediate between opposing political forces. In fact it can be argued that
the politicization of the army and the erosion of its ability to mediate between
opposing political forces are apparent from the nature of Pakistan’s military
regime. It has three characteristics which provide evidence for our arguments:
1. The fact that the military regime is not using a politically, natural
35Eqbal Ahmad, ‘Pakistan: Sign Posts to a Police State,’ Outlook, May, 18, 1974. 219
ideology (as was the Ayub regime) hut is using a particular form of
religious ideology hat is explicitly linked with the political position of a
particular political party (the Jamaat—i—lslami.)
2. The thinly veiled support of the regime for t lie Jamaat-i-Islami and more
importantly, the provision of access to the political apparatus of the
Jamaat into various institutions of the government.
3. The failure of the military regime to constitute a convincing civilian
facade behind which it can retract. Thus, for example, the president
General Zia—ul—Haq continued to retain the office of Chief of Army
Staff, even after the formal withdrawal of Martial Law.
The above three characteristics of the regime suggest that this military regime is
organically linked with particular political forces. Therefore the military cannot
now be regarded as having political ‘neutrality’ and relative autonomy on the
basis of which it is supposed to mediate opposing political forces or ‘sit in
judgment over them.’
PART III
CIVIL SOCIETY UNDERMINED
The ruling elite at the dawn of independence consisted of an alliance between the
landlords and nascent industrial bourgeoisie hacked by the military—
bureaucratic oligarchy. The nature of the ruling elite conditioned the form of the
economic growth process, I however, the latter in turn influenced the form in
which State power was exercised. Economic growth was of a kind that brought
affluence to the few at the expense of the many. The gradual erosion of social
infrastructure, endemic poverty and the growing inequality between regions
undermined civil society and accelerated the trend towards militarization. In this
section we will examine the relationship between an increasingly coercive State
structure, external dependence and the nature of economic growth during the
Bhutto and Zia periods respectively.
CONTRADICTIONS AND THE NATURE
OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: 1960—1970
The basic objective of the planning strategy during the decade of I he sixties Was
to achieve a high growth rate of GNP within the framework of private enterprise,
investment targets were to he achieved on the basis of the doctrine of ‘functional
inequality’. This meant deliberately transferring 1 from the poorer sections of
society who were thought to have a low marginal rate of savings, to high income
groups who were expected to have a high marginal rate of savings.36 It was
thought that by thus concentrating
36 It is clear that the distribution of national production should be such as to favor the
savings sectors. Government of Pakistan Planning Commission. The third Five Year
Plan, 1965-70 (Karachi: Government of Pakistan, May 1965), P. 33. 220
income in the hands of the rich, the total domestic savings, and hence the level of
investment, could be raised.’ It was argued that in the initial period when
domestic savings would he low, the gap between the target level o investment
and actual domestic savings would be filled by a large inflow of foreign aid. It
was thought that as growth proceeded and Income w transferred from the poor to
the rich, domestic savings would rise, until by the cud of the Perspective Plan in
1985, the country would become independent of foreign aid.38
During the decade of the sixties, the above strategy was put into practice, and at a
superficial level at least, in terms of its growth targets it was successful. For
example, the growth rate of GNP’ was 5.5 percent P annum; manufacturing
output increased by an average annual rate of about 8 percent, with large-scale
manufacturing increasing at over 10 percent per annum. The elite farmer strategy
of concentrating new agricultural inputs in the hands of rich farmers also bore
fruit by generating growth rate in agricultural output of 3.2 percent per annum
(compared to less than 1.5 percent in the previous decade). However, underlying
this impressive performance in terms of aggregate growth rates was an economy
which became structurally and financially so dependent on the advanced
capitalist countries that the very sovereignty of the State began to be undermined.
Apart from this, the nature of the growth process generated such acute
inequalities between regions that the internal cohesion of society began to he
seriously eroded.
The particular growth process in Pakistan generated four fundamental
contradictions:
1. A dependent economic structure and the associated high degree of
reliance on foreign aid.
2. An acute concentration of economic power in the hands of forty-three
families and the resultant gulf between the rich and the poor in urban
areas.
3. Growing economic disparity between regions.
4. Polarization of classes in the rural sector and a rapid increase in
landlessness.
Dependent Economic Structure
Underlying the apparently impressive figures of the growth of manufactured
output (10 percent per annum in the large-scale manufacturing sector) was an
inefficient and lopsided industrial structure. Growth was concentrate not in heavy
industries which could impart self—reliance to the economy but
37 Savings are a function not only of the level of income but also of its distribution
Mahbub-ul-Haq . Strategy of Economic Planning (Karachi: Oxford University Press,
1963), p. 30.
38 Government of Pakistan, Third Five Year Plan., P. 17. 221
rather in consumer goods produced with imported machines. Thus, by 1970—71,
cotton textiles alone accounted for as much as 48 percent of value added in industry,
while basic industries such as basic metals and electric and transport equipment
accounted for only I percent of the value added in manufacturing in Pakistan. Not
only was growth concentrated in consumer goods industries, but also the efficiency
of these industries was very low. This was due to the high degree of protection and
support given by the Government in the form of high import tariffs, an overvalued
exchange rate, tax holidays and provision of cheap credit industrialists could thus
earn annual profits of 50 percent to 100 percent or more and were under no pressure
to increase efficiency. Apart from this, export subsidies enabled manufacturers to
export goods at an extremely high rupee cost per dollar earned. In some cases, goods
were profitably exported at dollar prices, which were less than the dollar value of the
raw materials embodied in the goods.40
Given the failure to develop a heavy industrial base and time emphasis on import—
dependent consumer goods industries, the structure of Pakistan’s industry induced
increasing dependence on imported inputs. At the same time, the failure to increase
domestic savings pushed the economy further into reliance on foreign aid. The policy
of dist distributing income in favor of the industrialists succeeded, hut the
assumption that this would raise domestic savings over time failed to materialize.
Griffin points out, for example, that 15 percent of the resources annually generated in
the rural sector were transferred to the urban industrialists, and 63 percent to 85
percent of these transferred resources went into increased urban consumption.41 Far
from raising the domestic savings rate to the target level of 25 percent of GNP, the
actual savings rate never rose above 12 percent of GNP and in some years was as low
as 3 percent to 4 percent.42
The low domestic savings caused by the failure of capitalists to save out oh their
increased income resulted during the decade of the sixties in growing dependence on
foreign aid. According to Government of Pakistan figures foreign aid inflow
increased from US$ 373 million in 1950-55 to US$ 2.7 I million in 1965-70. 70This
seven-fold increase in the volume of aid was accompanied by a continuing change in
the composition of aid from grants to loans so that whereas ‘grant and grant—type’
assistance constituted 73
39 For a discussion of inefficiency of Pakistan’s industry. See. R Soligo and J J Stern,
“Tariff Protection, Import-Substitution and Investment Inefficiency,’ Pakistan
Development Review (Summer 1967). See also, C C Winston, ‘over-invoicing and
Industrial Efficiency, Pakistan Development Review (Winter 1970).
40 R D Mallon, ‘Export Policy in Pakistan, ‘ Pakistan Development Review (Spring
1966).
41K Grifin, ‘ Financing Development plans in Pakistan,’ in K Griffin and A R Khan (ed.),
Growth and Inequality in Pakistan (London: Macmillan, 1974), p. 133.
42Ibid., pp. 41-2
43Government of Pakistan, Finance Division, Pakistan Economic Survey, 1973-74
(Islamabad: Government of Pakistan, 1974), P. 133. 222
percent of total aid received during l950 this type of assistance declined to 9
percent by 1965-70. Thus, not only had the volume of aid increase dramatically
hut also the terms on which it was received became increasingly harder. The
result was that debt servicing alone by the end of the sixties constituted a
crippling burden. While debt servicing as a proportion of commodity export
earnings was 4.2 percent in 1960-61, by 1971—72 it had become 34.5 percent.
Clearly, such a magnitude of export earnings could not he spent on debt servicing
if vital food and industrial inputs were to be maintained. Thus, by the end of the
sixties, economic survival began to depend on getting more aid to pay hack past
debts. This pattern of aid dependence continues to this day. In 1986, for example,
73 percent of gross aid received was returned as payment for debt servicing
charges on past debt. What is perhaps even more significant is that the
conditionally clauses of ‘foreign aid’ specify in great detail the economic policy
that the Government of Pakistani is required to follow.44 Aid —giving agencies,
for example specify policies from the price of gas and fertilizer to import policy,
from the method of administering railways to the allocations to be made by t he
Government in each sect or of the economy. These increasingly comprehensive
macro—economic policy packages accompanying foreign aid seriously erode the
sovereignty of Pakistan’s economic decision—making.
Concentration of Economic Power
The process of economic growth upon which Pakistan embarked during the
sixties was designed to concentrate incomes iii the hands of the industrial elite n
the one Ii and arid the big landowners on the other. It is in surprising therefore
that by the end of the 1960s a small group of families with interlocking
directorates dominated industry, banking and insurance in Pakistan. Thus forty—
three families represented 76.8 percent of all manufacturing assets (including
foreign and government assets). In terms of value added 46 pet cent of the value
added in all large—scale manufacturing originated in firms controlled by forty—
three families.45
In banking, the degree of concentration was even greater than in industry. For
example, seven family banks constituted 91.6 percent of private domestic
deposits and 84.4 percent of earning assets. Furthermore, there is evidence to
show that the family banks tended to favor industrial companies controlled by the
same families in the provision of loans. State bank compilation of balance sheets
of listed companies indicates which banks industrial families were one of the two
to four banks that the industries controlled by the some industrial families dealt
with.46
44See ‘The Memorandum of Agreement between the Government of Pakistan and the
World Bank, 1980,’ (typescript). Also see ‘Economic Policy Memorandum of the
Government of Pakistan for 1981-82,’ May 1981 (mimeo).
45L J White, Industrial Concentration and Economic Power in Pakistan (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1972), p. 63.
45Ibid., pp. 74-5. 223
The insurance industry, although smaller in size than banking, also had a high
degree of concentration of ownership. The forty-three industrial families
controlling 75.6 percent of assets of Pakistani insurance companies tendered to
favour industrial companies owned by the same group. The insurance company
investments were used for providing a ready market for the shares of the
families’ industrial companies whenever they wished to sell shares without
depressing the share price. 47
The major industrial families and entrepreneurs were a fairly closely knit group.
Not only did many of them have caste and kinship relations, but members of the
families tended to sit on each other’s boards of directors. About one—third of the
seats on the boards of directors of companies controlled by the forty-three
families were occupied by members of other families within the forty-three. 48
Not only were the forty-three families dominating industry, insurance and
banking, they also had considerable Power over Government agencies
sanctioning industrial projects. For example, PICIC (Pakistan Industrial Credit
and Investment Corporation) was the agency responsible for sanctioning largescale
industrial projects. Out of the twenty-one directors of P1CIC, seven were
from the forty-three leading industrial families and were actively involved in the
administrative institutions that directly affected their economic interests.
During the process of rapid economic growth of the sixties, while an exclusive and
highly monopolistic class was amassing wealth, the majority of Pakistan’s population
was suffering an absolute decline in its living standards. For example, the per capita
consumption of food grain of the poorest 60 percent of Pakistan’s urban population
declined from an index of 100 in 1963—64 to 96.1 in 1969-70. The decline was even
greater over the same period in the case of the poorest 60 percent of rural population.
In their case, per capita consumption of food grain declined from an index of 100 in
1963—64 to only 91 in 1969—70.49 There was an even larger decline in real wages
in industry. For example, Griffin suggests that in the decade and a half ending in
1967, real wages in industry declined by 25 percent.50 S M Naseem, in a more recent
study for the I l. has estimated that in 1971-72 poverty in the rural sector was so
acute that 82 percent of rural households could not afford to provide even 2100
calories per day per family member. (2300 calories a day per head arc regarded as the
minimum for a healthy active life.)
Regional Economic Disparity
In an economy where investment takes place on the basis of private profitability
alone, there would be a cumulative tendency for investment to be
47Ibid., pp. 79—80.
48Ibid., pp. 81—5.
49N Hamid, ‘The Burden of Capitalist Growth: A Study of Real Wages in
Pakistan, Pakistan Economic and Social Review (Spring 1974)
50K Griffin and A R Khan, Growth and Inequality in Pakistan, op.cit., pp. 204-
205. 224
concentrated in the relatively developed regions. Consequently, regional
economic disparities would tend to widen over time. This is in fact what
happened in the case of Pakistan. Punjab and Sind provinces, which had
relatively more developed infrastructures, attracted a larger proportion of
industrial investment than the other provinces, in Sind, however, the growth in
income was mainly in Karachi and Hyderabad. Thus, economic disparities
widened not only between East and West Pakistan, but also between the
provinces within West Pakistan. during the sixties the factor which accelerated
the growth of regional income disparities within what is today Pakistan was the
differential impact of agricultural growth associated with the so-called ‘Green
Revolution’. Since the yield increase associated with the adoption of high—yield
varieties of foodgrain required Irrigation and since the Punjab and Sind had a
relatively larger proportion of their area under irrigation, they experience much
faster growth in their in conies, compared to Baluchistan and NWFP. 51
In a situation where each of the provinces of Pakistan had a distinct culture and
language, the systematic growth of regional disparities within the framework of
the market mechanism created acute political tensions, defusing these tensions
required a genuinely federal democratic structure with decentralization of
political power at the provincial level. Only such a polity and large federal
expenditures for the development of underdeveloped regions could ensure the
unity of the country in the absence of such a polity, the growing economic
disparities between provinces created explosive political tensions.
Polarization of Classes
The failure to conduct an effective land reform in Pakistan has resulted in a
continued concentration of landownership in the hands of a few big land lords.52
Thus, in 1972, 30 percent of total farm area was owned by large landowners
(owning 150 acres and above).53 The overall picture of Pakistanis agrarian
structure has been that these large landowners have rented out most of (heir land
to small and medium—sized tenants (i.e. tenants operating below twenty—five
acres).54 in such a situation, when the ‘Green Revolution’ technology became
available in the hate sixties, the large landowners found it profitable to resume
some of their rented—out land for
51For a detailed study of regional disparities within West Pakistan, see: N Hamid and A
Hussain, ‘Regional Inequalities and Capitalist Development, ‘Pakistan Economic and
Social review (Autumn 1974).
52For discussion and evidence on the failure of the attempts at land reforms in 1959 and
1972, see Akmal Hussain, ‘The Land Reforms in Pakistan: A Reconsideration, ‘ Bulletin
of Concerned Asian Scholars (Colorado, January – March, 1984).
53Ibid.
54Landowners with 150 acres and above rent out 75 percent of their owned area to
tenants operating 25 acres or less. See a Hussain, ‘Impact of Agricultural Growth on
Changes in the Agrarian Structure of Pakistan, 1960-1978, with Special Reference to the
Punjab Province (D. Phiol. Thesis, Sussex University, 1980). 225
self—cultivation on large farms using hired labour and capital investment. It is this
process of the development of capitalist farming which has generated new and
potentially explosive contradictions in Pakistan’s rural society. These contradictions
have resulted from the highly unequal distribution of landownership.
During the period when high-yielding varieties of foodgrains were being adopted,
there was a rapid introduction of tractors. The number of tractors increased from
2,000 in 1959 to 18,909 in l968.55 By 1975 there were 35,714 tractors with an
additional 76,000 tractors being imported between I976 and 1981.56 Significantly,
most of these tractors were large sized in a country where 91 percent of the farms are
below twenty-five acres, and about 57 percent of total farm area is operated in farms
below twenty-five acres.
An important reason why large tractors were introduced was that large landowners,
responding to the new profit opportunities; began to resume rented—out land for
self—cultivation of large farms. Given the difficulty of mobilizing a large number of
laborers during the peak Season in an imperfect labor market and supervising
laborers to ensure satisfactory performance, the large farmers found it convenient to
mechanize even though there is no labor shortage in an absolute sense.
As a result of the development of capitalism in agriculture, polarization has occurred
in the size distribution of farms, especially in the Punjab; i.e., the percentage share of
large and small tar ms Is Increasing, while t lie percentage share of medium-sized
farms (eight to twenty-five acres) is declining.57 This Polarization is essentially the
result of large landowners resuming their rented—out land for self-cultivation on
large farms. The land resumption had the greatest has had the greatest impact on
medium sized tenants.
Along with polarization in the rural class structure, landlessness has increased
because many tenants are evicted following land resumption by big landowners. It
has been estimated that during the decade of the sixties, 794,042 peasants became
landless laborers; i.e. 43 percent of the total agricultural laborers had entered this
category following proletarianization of the poor peasantry.58
Unlike Europe, where the growth of capitalism in agriculture was associated with the
emancipation of the peasantry, in Pakistan the development of capitalist farming has
intensified the dependence of the poor peasantry. The reason is that in Pakistan
capitalist farming has occurred in a situation where the political and economic power
of the landlords is still intact. Consequently, the big landlord is able to control local
institutions for the distribution of credit and other inputs. The result is that the poor
peasant, in order to buy tube well water, seeds, fertilizer and pesticides and to market
his output, has to depend on the good offices of the landlord. Thus, as the
55Akrnal Hussain, ‘ Land Reforms in Pakistan: A Reconsideration,’ op. cit.
56Ibid.
57Akmal Hussain, Impact of Agricultural Growth. 1960-78,’ op. cit.
58Akmal Hussain, ‘ The Land Reforms in Pakistan: A reconsideration, ‘ op. cit. 226
inputs for agricultural production become monetized and insofar as access to the
market is via the landlord, the poor peasant’s dependence h intensified.
As money costs of inputs increased without a proportionate increase in yield per
acre of the poor peasant (due to poor timing and inadequate inputs) his real
income is being reduced. Evidence shows that both the quantity and quality of
diet of poor peasants have deteriorated. 59
The particular form that. capitalist farming in Pakistan has taken s increasing
landlessness, unemployment, class polarization and Poverty. Each of these
features has arisen because capitalist farming is occurring in a situation where
landownership is highly unequal, and where the feudal power of the landlords is
intact.
CLASS COMPOSITION OF THE PAKISTAN PEOPLE’S
PARTY AND THE STATE APPARATUS
The PPP was originally composed of radical elements of the petit bourgeoisie of
the Punjab and Sind on the one hand and substantial elements of capitalist
farmers on the other. The radical elements of the petit bourgeoisie were dominant
in the PPP until 1972, This was evident from its manifesto which was anti—
imperialist, anti feudal, and against monopoly capitalism. The same stratum also
played a key role in devising a propaganda machine suited to the manifesto and
presenting it as a ‘revolutionary’ program, thereby getting the support of the
urban workers and the poor peasantry.
The radical stratum was drawn from diverse social origins and had differing
political objectives, and its members therefore connected themselves to Bhutto in
separate groups or factions. The inability of different factions of the radical petit
bourgeoisie to constitute themselves into a single block within the PPP facilitated
the purges that came after 1972.
By 1972 Bhutto had consolidated his power and began to shift the balance of
class forces within the PPP in favor of the landlord group. This shift was not
accidental, nor was it a personal betrayal of the radicals on Bhutto’s Part as it was
subjectively experienced by the party cadres. Changes in the internal class
composition of the PPP were objectively determined by the changed position of
the PPP in relation to the State. In the pre—election period the dominance of the
radical petit bourgeoisie and its political rhetoric were necessary if the PPP was
to get a mass base for an election victory.
After the election, Bhutto realized that if the socialist rhetoric of the left wing of
the PPP was to be implemented, it could not be done through the existing State
apparatus. It would involve institutionalizing party links with the working class
and the peasantry by building grass-roots organizations. This would soon
generate a working—class leadership which would not only threaten his own
position within the party but would also unleash a momentum
59 Ibid. 227
of class conflict that would place the PPP on a collision course with the military
and the bureaucracy. Given Bhutto’s own commitment to seek social democratic
reforms within the framework of the State as constituted at the time, he was
unwilling to take a path that would lead to a confrontation with the State
apparatus. Consequently, the socialist rhetoric of the PM’ had to be toned down,
its radical petit bourgeoisie elements quietened or purged from the party, the
rudimentary organizational links with the working class and poor peasants
broken and the landlord elements of the PM firmly established as the dominant
element within the party.
The decision to purge the radical elements within the PPP and to separate it
structurally from its worker-peasant base meant that Bhutto had to rely on the
bourgeois State apparatus to respond to the political challenges emanating from
three directions: First, the intensification of the nationalist struggle in
Baluchistan; second, the growing militancy of the working class in the Punjab
and Sind; and finally, parties representing the industrial bourgeoisie.
The strategy of selective repression of the political opposition necessitated
changes in the State apparatus so as to make it more effective as a coercive
instrument. Bhutto brought about three types of changes:
1. He streamlined and strengthened the internal security service and formed a
new paramilitary organization called the Federal Security Force, consisting
initially of 10,000 men. This was essentially a political police force
responsible directly to the Prime Minister
2. An attempt was made to reduce the power and autonomy of the elite CSP
(Civil Services of Pakistan) cadre of the bureaucracy. This was done first by
purging 1,300 officers on grounds of misuse of power and filling their
vacancies by pro-PPP men. Second, a new system of lateral entry was
instituted. Trough this, direct appointments at all levels of the administrative
services were made on recommendation from the PPP leadership. By the
short—circuiting the hierarchy of the CSP and penetrating it with officers
who were loyal to the PPP, large sections of the bureaucracy were
politicized and made more amenable for use by the PPP.
3. In the armed forces, Bhutto conducted two purges in quick succession. He
first discarded the five top generals who had dominated the Government
before and during the Bangladesh crisis, and second, he ousted those
commanders like Lieutenant General Gul Hassan Khan and Air Marshal
Rahim Khan who had been instrumental in the transfer of power to Bhutto
himself. Thus, enemies and benefactors alike were removed on grounds that
they had Bonapartist tendencies. The new chief of the army staff was Tikka
Khan, who was succeeded by Zia-ul-Haq, whom Butto promoted by
superseding four other generals in the hope that he would be obliged to be
loyal. However, as was realized later, a coup d’etat cannot be prevented by
simply placing loyal generals in command. What is necessary is to change
the 228
very structure of the armed forces anti its relationship to the political
system. What he had to (10 to prevent a COUP was to subordinate the
armed forces as an institution to the political system. This change in the
structural position of the armed forces within the State, from position of
dominance to a position of subordination to the political system, could
only have been achieved by organizationally linking the PPP to its mass
base. This was something that Bhutto was not pr pared to do.
While Bhutto in his attempt to use the State apparatus to quell political opposition
was internalizing some sections of the State apparatus into his political apparatus, a
parallel process of infiltration was being covertly conducted by another political
party: The Jamaat-i-Islami.
The Jamaat-i-Islami is an extreme right-wing religious party composed of the most
retrograde section of the urban petit bourgeoisie. It had suffered a humiliating
electoral defeat in 1970, having obtained only 5 percent of the vote and three
National Assembly seats. After this defeat it started concentrating on preparing for a
COUP by increasing its infiltration of the army and bureaucracy. 60 The Jamaat from
it very inception was a semisecret, extreme right-wing organization of disciplined
cadres, some of whom ate given combat training. After 1970 it was able to expand its
influence over strategic Sections of the State apparatus for a number of reasons:
1. The earlier generation of generals in the high command were British trained,
liberal officers, drawn largely from the affluent landowning class. However,
in the sixties a new generation of officers began to occupy command
positions. These were less literate and more religious, drawn largely front
the economically depressed migrants Potwar region of West Punjab (like
General Zia-ul-Haq) and the unirrigated Potwar region of West Punjab. This
new generation of officers was socially more conservative than the earlier
generation, was brought tip in a religious culture and was highly susceptible
to the puritanical ideology of the Jamaat. 61
2. Similarly, patterns of general recruitment in the army had changed whereby
many of the rank and file as well as the junior officers tended to come not
from the prosperous central Punjab, hut from the relatively impoverished
northern districts of the province, where a fundamentalist religious ethos still
prevails. 62
3. The demoralization of the armed forces following the defeat ill Bangladesh
had opened the way for an obscurantist ideology. In the absence of
ideological work among the ranks by the left, the average soldier turned to
the lslamism of the Jamaat for an explanation both of his failure as well as
his future purpose. 63
60For a more detailed description of the Jamaat-i-Islami, See Aijaz Ahmad, ‘Democracy
and Dictatorship in Pakistan, ‘Journal of Contemporary Asia (Winter, 1978).
61Ibid., p. 503.
62Ibid.
63Ibid. 229
4. The Jamaat propaganda among troops was tolerated and in some cases
sanctioned by commanding officers at the battalion level and above. 64
It appears that the relative autonomy and internal coherence of the State
apparatus has been considerably undermined due to its infiltration by PPP
sympathizers on the one hand and by Jamaat cadres on the other. The consequent
factionalizing process within the armed forces and the bureaucracy is an
important factor in the nature of the July 1977 coup as well as an element in the
present crisis of the State.
SOCIO-ECONOMIC CAUSES OF THE ANTI-BHUTTO
MOVEMENT, AND THE BHUTTO LEGACY
The essential political aspect of the nationalization of nine basic industries, banks
and insurance companies was that it enabled the PPP to buy the political support
of a section of the urban petit bourgeoisie through provision of credit and
contracts for consultancy, construction projects and production of components.
The nationalization of banks particularly enabled the PPP to strengthen its
support among the kulaks by providing them with low—interest loans. For
example, in 1975 alone, Rs 1,650 million were provided to kulaks. In the period
1971—72 to 1975—76, loans from nationalized ‘commercial banks for tractors
and tubewells increased by 400 percent and loans for other farm needs (so-called
taccavi loans) increased by 600 percent. Similarly, Government subsidies for
chemical fertilizers rose from US $2.5 million to US $60 million during the
period 1971 to 1976. The same rapid expansion of rural credit is indicated by
loans given by the Agricultural Development Bank
1971—1972 1975—1976
Tractors Rs 370.41 million Rs 2,200 million
Tubewells Rs 180.41 million Rs 860.67 million
The nationalization of banks and the subsequent credit expansion for financing
loans to industries and capitalist farming led to heavy deficit financing and an
increase in the money supply. Thus, notes in circulation Increased from Rs
23,000 million in 1971—72 to Rs. 57,000 million in 1976—77. There was a
sharp slowing in the growth rate of both agriculture and industry. Thus, industrial
growth fell from an average of 13 percent per year during the sixties to only 3
percent per year during the Bhutto period from 1972 to 1977. Similarly, the
agricultural growth rate declined from an average of 5.65 percent in the sixties to
a mere 0.45 percent in the period l970-75
64Ibid 230
The sharp increase in the money supply during a period of virtual stag nation in
agriculture and industry was reflected in a very sharp rise in the rate of inflation.
The wholesale price index at 1959—60 prices rose from 150.3 in 1971—72 to
288.8 by 1974—75, with the sharpest increase being recorded in foodgrain
prices, which rose by 200 percent over the three-year period. It appears then that,
although nationalization of industry and credit expansion enabled the PPP to buy
the support of a section of the urban petit bourgeoisie through the provision of
jobs, contracts, licenses and loans, the available funds and contracts were not
large enough to enrich the entire petit bourgeoisie. In fact a section of the lower
middle class that did not gain from the PPP, suffered an absolute decline in their
real incomes due to the high inflation rate. It was the frustrated section of the
urban petit bourgeoisie and the large lumpen proletariat which had been stricken
by inflation that responded to the call for a street agitation in March 1977.
Although the apparent form of the street agitation was spontaneous, it was
orchestrated and given political focus at key junctures of the movement. This
organizational and coordinating function was performed by the highly trained
cadres of the Jamaat-i-Islami. The agitation was of course fueled by the fart that
the P1’ was alleged to have rigged elections in a number of constituencies,
although it was subsequently recognized that the PPP would have won a majority
even without the rigging
While internal factors were important determinants of the anti-Bhutto movement,
nevertheless they must be seen in the context of the inter national forces at play
during the last days of the Bhutto regime. Bhutto by means of his nuclear
program and his diplomacy with the Arab regimes was attempting to acquire
leverage against the power of the United States in the region. His defiance in the
face of US disapproval of his policies occurred in a situation where his domestic
political support had not been secured and institutionalized through a political
party. This was a factor as important in his overthrow as the organized opposition
by elements of the petit bourgeoisie. The overthrow of the Bhutto regime and the
subsequent hanging of the only popularly elected Prime Minister of Pakistan
dramatically represented the limits of populism within a State structure
dominated by the military—bureaucratic oligarchy. Through his charismatic
personality and populist rhetoric Bhutto had in his early years galvanized mass
consciousness and unleashed powerful popular forces. His us failure to
institutionalize these essentially spontaneous forces within a grass—roots party
and the resultant failure to subordinate the military—bureaucratic elite to the
political system led to his tragic downfall. Yet, the style and content Bhutto’s
political message has left a lasting legacy in the popular consciousness: That the
poor have the right and the ability to be freed of the shackles of oppression: that
they too can dream of threatening the citadels of power. His lonely defiance of
military authority during his months in the death cell has given this dream an
immediacy and the Bhutto name an intense emotional charge. 231
MILITARIZATION AND DEPENDENCE UNDER THE ZIA REGIME
The Fragmentation of Civil Society
Each regime that came to power sought to legitimize itself through an explicit
Ideology: The Ayub regime propounded the ideology of modernization and
economic development. The Bhutto regime sought legitimacy in the ideology of
redeeming the poor (‘Food, Clothing and Shelter for all’) through socialism. It is
an index of Zia’s fear of popular forces, that the initially sought justification of
his government precisely in its temporary character. If anything, it was the
ideology of transience (That he was there for only 90 days for the sole purpose of
holding fair elections). It was this fear that impelled the Zia regime to seek (albeit
through a legal process) the physical elimination of the one individual who could
mobilize the popular forces. It was the same fear that subsequently induced Zia to
rule on the basis of military terror while propounding a version of Islamic
ideology. Draconian measures of military courts, arbitrary arrests and public
lashings were introduced. Thus the gradual erosion since independence of the
institutions of civil society, brought the power of the State into stark
confrontation with the people. Earlier in 1971, this confrontation had been a
major factor in the break—Lip of Pakistan and the creation of an independent
Bangladesh. Now a protracted period of Martial 1 aw under the Zia regime
served to brutalize and undermine civil society in what remained of Pakistan.
As the Zia regime militarized the State structure, its isolation from the people
was matched by its acute external dependence. In the absence of domestic
political popularity it sought political, economic and military support from the
United States. This pushed Pakistan into becoming a ‘front line State’ in
America’s Afghan war which was an important factor iii further undermining
civil society.
Since 1977, with the steady inflow into Pakistan of Afghan refugees and use of
Pakistan as a conduit for arms for the Afghan war, two trends have emerged to
fuel the crisis of civil society:
1. A large proportion of weapons meant for the Afghan guerrillas have
filtered into the illegal arms market.
2. There has been a rapid growth of the heroin trade. Powerful mafia- type
syndicates have emerged which operate the production. domestic
transportation and export of heroin. Many Afghan refugees who now
have a significant share of intercity overland cargo services have also
been integrated into the ding syndicates.
The large illegal arms market and the burgeoning heroin trade have Injected both
weapons and syndicate organizations into the social life major urban centers. At
the same I hue the frequent bombings in the NWFP resulting from the Afghan
war and the weakening of State authority in 232
parts of rural Sind has undermined for many people confidence in the basic
function of the State: That of providing security of life to its citizens. Under these
circumstances it is not surprising that an increasing number of people are seeking
alternative support mechanisms in their communities to seek redress against
Injustice and to achieve security against a physical threat to their per and
families. The proximate identity or group membership through which the
individual seeks such security can be an ethnic, sub religious, sub-nationalist or
biraderi (kinship) group. Thus, civil society has begun to get polarized along
vertical lines. Each group, whether ethnic, sub-religious, sub-nationalist or
biraderi, has an intense emotional charge and a high degree of firepower derived
from the contemporary arms market.
The Mechanism of Economic Dependence Under the Zia Regime
The development strategy under the Martial Law regime was formulated within
the framework of the IMF/World Bank Structural Adjustment Program. This is a
comprehensive macro-economic policy package which constitutes IMF/World
Bank conditionality and contains three principal policy guidelines:
1. Import liberalization
2. Withdrawal of subsidies
3. Exchange rate devaluation.
These guidelines arc essentially interrelated and effectively propose that the
economy he ‘opened up’ to the flows of foreign goods and capital and that
resource allocation in the domestic economy take place on the basis of world
market prices. Import liberalisation and withdrawal of subsidies from local goods
means that foreign goods would he freely available locally and compete more
effectively against domestically produced goods whose pi ices would rise as the
result of subsidy withdrawal. Apart from this, formerly overvalued exchange
rates constituted an implicit subsidy to domestic industrialists using imported
inputs. This too would he withdrawn following exchange rate devaluation. As
import expenditures following import liberalization increase and export earnings
from manufactured goods using imported inputs fall, there would consequently
arise an acute pressure on I he balance of payments. I fence, exchange rate
devaluation, which is the third clement in the I Mi/WV policy package, would
induce a downward adjustment in the exchange rate as a device to sustain import
liberalization and subsidy withdrawal.
The overall effect of this policy would be that resource allocation in the domestic
economy would take place in response to world market prices. This means that
the domestic resources would tend to be concentrate the agriculture sector where
the country has a comparative advantage (in a static sense) and a shift away from
the strategy of industrialization., which was an emblem of national independence
in the post—colonial period. In such 233
a development strategy growth of (NP is predicated primarily on the agriculture
sector and foreign exchange earnings critically dependent Oil agricultural
exports. Accordingly, while readily available agricultural goods would enable an
increase in foreign exchange earnings in the short run, the decline in the terms of
trade against agricultural exporters and the low ceiling to agricultural growth,
would combine to restrict the growth of export earnings in the long run. Thus, the
IMF/WB policy package while would Create the capacity to service debts in the
short term, would Constrain the growth of foreign exchange in the long run, and
hence maintain a continued dependence of the national economy on foreign
loans.
Let us now consider how the IMF/WB conditionality was implemented in
Pakistan, and then examine its implications for industrialization and planning in
this country.
The Sixth Five Year Plan which was formulated by the Martial 1 aw regime
reflects the Structural Adjustment Program imposed on Pakistan’s planners as a
condition for the loans given by the IMF/WB. The Sixth Plan places emphasis on
resource allocation based on present comparative advantage, 65 agriculture as the
basis of achieving aggregate GNP growth targets and concentration on
agricultural exports. For example, the World Hank Review of the Plan states:
‘The plan’s principal objectives are to achieve a major breakthrough in
agricultural production, an expanding foothold in export markets for agricultural
products, rapid development of selected industries in which the country has a
comparative advantage . . .
The Plan document itself makes clear the strategy of making agriculture (rather
than industry) as the spearhead of growth in GNP: ‘. . . the growth strategy of the
Plan is based on a major breakthrough in agriculture production . . . ‘66It goes on
to emphasize the objective of agricultural exports:
The growth strategy of the Plan relies on a combination of policies including:
1. A major increase in agricultural yields through more efficient use of
fertilizer, water and farm technology.
2. An expanding foothold in export markets for wheat and rice as well as
for fruits, vegetables, flowers, poultry and meat.
3. Increased self-sufficiency in oil seeds.
4. Rapid development of steel based engineering goods; modernization of
textile industry and establishment of agro-industries for processing
agricultural surpluses…67
The policy of import liberalization, subsidy withdrawal and resource
65 World Bank, Pakistan: A Review of the Sixth live Year Plan, A World Bank Country Study
(Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 1956, p. 17).
66 Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan, The Sixth Five Year Plan I983-88, p. 11.
67 Ibid. 234
allocation based on the market mechanism is indicated clearly in the World Bank
Review of the Sixth Plan:
Another significant feature of the Plan is the expanding role assigned to the
private sector. With private investment projected to increase more than twice as
rapidly as public investment, and the involvement of the public sector in
manufacturing to decline sharply, the attainment of the overall targets of the Plan
will depend to a greater extent than in the past on the performance of the private
sector. . . As is recognized in the Plan, major actions in pricing, deregulation,
tariffs and import liberalization and other incentives will be needed to induce the
private sector to play the iii- creased role expected of it . . . (emphasis mine). 68
The implementation of the third element in the conditionality package of the
IMF/WB (indicated above), namely devaluation of the rupee, was done by means
of de-linking the rupee from the fixed exchange rate with the dollar and putting
the rupee on a ‘managed float’ with a weighted average of the currencies of
Pakistan’s major trading partners. This resulted in effectively devaluing the rupee
against the dollar by 37.9 percent between January 1982 and May 1985.69 As
suggested in the foregoing analysis, the imperative to devalue the exchange rote
arises as the result of pressure on the balance of payments associated with import
liberalization, subsidy withdrawal and reliance on agricultural exports which are
subject to declining terms of trade. Thus in Pakistan, after an initial increase in
foreign exchange earnings and a strong balance of payments position between
1978 to 1982, export earnings declined sharply by 17.3 percent in 1983.70 The
balance of payments continued to deteriorate in subsequent years until in March
1985 the gross foreign exchange reserves fell drastically to $883 million which is
equivalent to only 1.6 months of import expenditures.71 One of the most
important factors in the deterioration in the balance of payments, and the
resultant increase in the reliance on foreign loans was a deterioration in
Pakistan’s terms of trade in a situation where its exportable are mainly
agricultural goods. Thus, terms of trade have been declining steadily from 87.5 in
1978—79 to 60 in 1983_84. 72
We have argued in the foregoing analysis that Pakistan has moved towards the
implementation of each of the major elements of the IMF/W conditionality
package which the latter prescribes for loan receiving countries, namely, import
liberalization, withdrawal of subsidies and exchange rate devaluation. The Sixth
Plan has explicitly adopted the framework of resource allocation in response to
world market prices on the basis of
68 World Bank, Pakistan: A Review of the Sixth Five Year Plan, op. cit., p. 17. 69 Government of 1 Pakistan Economic Survey 1954.85 70 Ibid.
71 Ibid.
72 Ibid. 235
private profitability criteria, i.e., agriculture as the spearhead of growth of GNP
and agricultural exports as the major instrument of foreign exchange earnings. In
so far as this has occurred, the Sixth Plan represents a marginalization of
planning in the process of economic growth. For the basic premise of economic
planning in an underdeveloped economy is that the present comparative
advantage imposes a structure of production (i.e., specialization in raw material
production) that works against the long—term interests of tile economy and the
free market mechanism merely reinforces the existing structure of production.
Hence planning is thought to be necessary to pull the economy out of the existing
structure of production based on specialization in agriculture towards one based
on industrialization. The logic of planning is that the existing set of world prices
is not an appropriate indicator for resource allocation. Insofar as the Sixth Plan
has explicitly adopted world prices and comparative advantage as the basis of
resource allocation, it constitutes an abandonment of National Economic
Planning iii the strict sense of the term.
CONCLUSION
The current crisis of the State in Pakistan has arisen out of a State structure in
which the dominance of the military—bureaucratic oligarchy systematically
constrained the development of the political process. The oligarchy devised a
political framework which, while allowing rivalry between the landlords and the
industrial bourgeoisie for the division of the economic surplus, maintained the
mode of appropriation of the surplus through which the existence of these elites
could be perpetuated.
The predominance of the army and bureaucracy in the structure of State Power in
Pakistan was due to the form of the freedom struggle in the pre partition period
on the one hand, and the nature of the Muslim League on
The other. At the time of independence, the state apparatus of the colonial regime
was largely intact, and it articulated the framework within which politics were to
occur. The second factor in the failure to subordinate the army and bureaucracy
to the political system lay in the two basic characteristics of both the Muslim
League before partition and the Pakistan People’s Party during the seventies:
1. Both the Muslim League in the pre—partition period as well as the
Pakistan people’s Party during the seventies were movements rat her
(11811 parties. They were therefore unable to establish an organizational
structure on the basis of which the power of the people could be
institutionalized and used to subordinate the army and the bureaucracy to
the political system.
2. The Muslim League in the decade before partition, and the PPP during
the early seventies, were taken over by landlords whose political interest
lay in constraining the process of political development within the
confines specified by the military—bureaucratic oligarchy. 236
The nature of economic growth which occurred in an economy dominated by the
landlords and the industrial bourgeoisie generated acute economic inequality
between the rich and the poor on the one hand and between regions on the other.
These economic contradictions manifested themselves in growing political
tensions between social groups and regions—tensions which could have been
mitigated (although not necessarily resolved) only within a democratic political
system that was responsive to the aspirations of the dispossessed classes and
poorer regions. As it was, in a State structure within which the political system
was severely constrained by the military- bureaucratic oligarchy, these tensions
merely built up pressure on the State structure.
The growing political tensions between social groups and regions developed at a
time when the relative autonomy of the military—bureaucratic oligarchy was
being eroded as the result of its politicization. ‘I while the task of mediating the
conflicting political forces became increasingly difficult, the ability of the
military-bureaucratic oligarchy to do so became weaker. Consequently, as civil
society became polarized the State increasingly used coercive forms of control.
Unlike the earlier Martial I .aw governments, the Zia regime was unable to
effectively hand over power to its civilian facade. Thus, in spite of formally
declaring the end of Martial Law, the posts of Chief of Army Staff and the
President continued to be held by General Zia—ul—Haq. This has made possible
the presence of the military in the daily affairs of the State. It has also created the
institutional basis of short—circuiting the civil administration by the military
chain of command, whenever this is felt necessary by the Chief of Army Staff. It
is in this perspective that the following major elements of the crisis of State and
civil society can be understood:
1. The State dominated by the repressive apparatus is highly centralized and is
unable to recognize, let alone grant, the rights of the various nationalities.
This has enhanced sub-national tendencies, given the fact that the army is
drawn predominantly from the Punjab province.
2. The State’s interpretation of religion is seen by the people as sanctifying
particular class interests and justifying repression against those who dare to
question it. The State is, therefore, bereft of a legitimizing ideology. For this
reason the army, unlike in the past, cannot withdraw behind a civilian
facade.
3. The prolonged military rule and the demise of the 1973 constitution have
eroded the balance between the various institutions of the State, i.e., the
armed forces, the bureaucracy, the judiciary, etc. There is, therefore, an
institutional crisis of State authority.
4. The fragmentation of civil society along various sub-religious, ethnic,
biraderi and sub-regional lines, and the rapid arming of conflicting groups
has weakened the basic function of the State: The protection of life of the
ordinary citizen This has accentuated the tendency of the individual to seek
security in the most proximate identity, and to militantly assert this parochial
identity as an emblem of his membership in it.
No comments:
Post a Comment