FINAL VERSION
INSTITUTIONAL IMPERATIVES OF
POVERTY REDUCTION
By
Akmal Hussain
Distinguished Professor,
Beaconhouse National University
Lahore
Institute of Public Policy,
Beaconhouse National University, Lahore
17th April 2008 1
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The author wishes to thank Dr. Hafiz Pasha for his guidance and support in
writing this paper. In particular his advice regarding the methodology for
estimates in table 7 is appreciated, without implicating him. Also
acknowledged is a debt of gratitude to Dr. Shahid J. Burki, Mr. Sartaj Aziz,
Dr. Parvez Hassan and Dr. Aisha Pasha for valuable comments and
suggestions on an earlier draft. Thanks are also due to Mr. Ahsan Shah for
research assistance and to Mr. Muhammad Azeem for typing successive
drafts. The responsibility however for the analysis, the views expressed and
any errors that might remain rests with the author alone.2
INSTITUTIONAL IMPERATIVES OF
POVERTY REDUCTION
By
Akmal Hussain
Ms. Bushra, a poor 30 year old woman, threw herself in front of a moving
train in Lahore together with her two children, Saima, age 3 and Zubair,
age 5. The mother is reported to have covered the eyes of her children
before all three were crushed under the train. She left a suicide note
written in the copy book of Zubair in the school satchel found near the site
of the tragedy. In the suicide note Ms. Bushra stated poverty as the cause
of her decision to commit suicide along with her children. [News Report
in the daily Dawn, 13th April 2008].
He who is without empathy for the suffering of others, has no right to be called human.
[Jalal-ud-Din Rumi, 1207-73]
INTRODUCTION: POVERTY AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE
The high food inflation in the last three years has pushed 11 million people into a state of
hunger and poverty. Given the present trend, if no policy action is taken, an additional 22
million people will be impoverished over the next four years. (See Table 7). According to
the World Food Programme Survey for the Vulnerability Analysis and Mapping Unit as
many as 77 million people upto March 2008 are deemed “food insecure”1
, where the food
insecure population is defined as those consuming less than 2350 calories per person per
day. The statistical evidence clearly shows Pakistan is in the grip of a poverty crisis. Ms.
Bushra’s action stands as stark testimony of the human experience of poverty. It also
poses a challenge to policy makers as much as to economists to undertake urgent policy
action on the basis of a scientific analysis of the problem. 3
This paper is an attempt to provide such an analysis and the outline of possible public
action to address the poverty crisis.
The poor in Pakistan like all human beings have a creative potential. Yet by being denied
the minimum of food and basic necessities, such as health, education and employment
opportunities, they are rendered incapable of actualizing their human potential.2
In understanding this constraint to human development, the poor in Pakistan cannot
simply be seen as individuals with certain adverse ‘resource endowments’, making
choices in free markets. Poverty occurs when the individual in a fragmented community
is locked into a nexus of power, which deprives the poor of their actual and potential
income. The poor face markets, institutions and local power structures, which
discriminate against access of the poor over resources, public services and governance
decisions which affect their immediate existence. (A. Hussain, 2000)3
.
This paper provides evidence to show that the poor have unequal access over capital, land
and labour markets. It is argued therefore that inequality and poverty are built into the
structure of the growth process itself. It is now widely recognized that inequality
adversely affects both the sustainability of growth as well as its capacity for poverty
reduction (WB Report, 2006)4
. The power structure, and the inequality it engenders,
excludes a large proportion of the population (poor, women, the sick and the illiterate).
Therefore there is a constriction of the human potential through which entrepreneurship,
investment, innovation and productivity growth can occur to sustain GDP growth5
.
Until 2003, most studies on poverty in Pakistan had examined the problem simply in
terms of measuring the number of people below certain poverty lines. However if poverty
is to be overcome, it is important to understand the processes of poverty creation and to
identify points of intervention in the process through which the poor can be enabled to
overcome poverty on a sustainable basis. In this context some of the questions that arise
are: How do distorted markets for inputs and outputs of goods and services result in the
loss of the actual or potential income of the poor? How do local structures of power with
respect to landlords, local administrative officials, and institutions for the provision of
health, credit and dispute resolution, deprive the poor of their income, assets and the 4
fruits of their labour? These questions will be examined in section-I of this paper. Equally
important for an understanding of the nature of poverty and the growth process is the
question of how the institutional structures of governance and the incentive systems
embodied in government policy constrain growth and poverty reduction.
The argument in this paper is that poverty is rooted in the institutional structure of society
and state in Pakistan. Therefore overcoming poverty will involve inducing changes in
both the polity and the economy as part of an integrated process of institutional change
(A. Hussain, 2008)6
. As North has argued, the polity is the fundamental basis of
economic performance7
. This is because it is in the realm of the polity that the “rules of
the game” and the associated incentive systems for the economy, are stipulated. In this
paper however while acknowledging the primary role of the polity, we will focus on
institutional changes in the economy as the basis of sustainable growth with equity.
(North, Wallis and Weingast 2006)8
.
It is in moving towards a stable democratic constitutional order that Pakistan can create
the institutional conditions for sustained and equitable growth: opportunities in the polity
and economy for all citizens, merit based selection, competition, efficiency and
innovation. Thus the path to democracy within a stable constitutional order is also the
path to sustainable and equitable economic growth.
In sections I and II of this paper we identify the structural factors that constrain growth
and induce endemic poverty. These structural factors are located in the institutional
framework that conditions both markets and governance. In section-III we briefly
indicate some of the policies for institutional change in the medium term that can be
undertaken to overcome the structural constraints to equitable growth. In section IV, an
analysis of poverty trends during the Musharraf regime (1999-2008), is presented,
together with new estimates of the impact of food inflation on poverty during the last
three years to suggest that a poverty crisis is at hand. At the end of section-IV, short term
policy actions for addressing the poverty crisis are outlined. 5
I. MARKETS, INSTITUTIONS AND POVERTY
In this section we will examine the four features of the power structure that makes
markets asymmetric to function adversely against the poor.
I.1 Power, Tenancy and Tied Labour
In landlord dominated areas, where landlords control the local state apparatus as well as
the credit market the poor tenants are locked into a nexus of power and debt bondage
with the landlord. Consequently the tenants are obliged to work part time on the
landlord’s farm as labourers either at less than market wage or no wage at all. The NHDR
survey data shows that 51 percent of the tenants get locked into debt dependence on the
landlord, and out of these, 57 percent are obliged to work as labourers on the landlord’s
farm without wages, while 14 percent work for a wage below the market rate (Hussain
et.al., 2003)9
. Thus the structure of power and dependence creates distortions in the
labour and capital markets, which systematically deprive the poor of their actual and
potential income. The consequent inefficiency in the allocation of labour and capital
resources constrains agricultural growth, increases inequality and engenders persistent
poverty. (See table 1).
TABLE 1
LOAN DEPENDENCE ON THE LANDLORD AND LABOUR EXPLOITATION
OF THE POOR PEASANTRY
Extremely
Poor
Poor Non-Poor Total
Loan from landlord (%) 50.8 29.4 11.7 34.4
Work for landlord against
wages (%)
14.0 24.3 5.1 16.9
Daily wages (Rupees) 28.0 43.6 60.0 40.0
Work for landlord
without wages (%)
57.4 38.5 25.4 43.5
SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001. 6
I.2 Power and the Double Squeeze on the Peasantry
In landlord dominated areas the landlord’s power impacts the disposal of the produce by
poor farm households which have direct consequences for their food consumption. As the
following table 2 shows, under asymmetric tennurial arrangements, the extremely poor
farmers are obliged to pay a larger proportion of their farm produce to the landlord as
rent, compared to other categories of the peasantry. For example, the extremely poor have
to pay 28.21% of their production value to the landlord, compared to 13.39% by the poor
households and only 8.41% by the non-poor households. Consequently, the extremely
poor households are forced to keep only 39.59% of their crop output for household
consumption, compared to 48% by poor households and 54% by non-poor households.
TABLE 2
DISPOSAL OF CROP HARVEST BY INCOME CLASS
Total
Production
Value
Paid in kind
to labour
(Value)/Tota
l Production
Value* 100
Paid as
rent
(Value)
/Total
Production
Value* 100
Paid to
landlord
under share
cropping
agreement
(Value)/
Total
Production
Value* 100
Given to
Relatives
(Value)/
Total
Production
Value* 100
Crop Sold
(Value)
/Total
Production
Value* 100
Crop Kept
for Own
Use/Total
Production
Value* 100
Extremely Poor 13864 1.45 1.10 28.21 0.09 29.57 39.59
Poor 22538 2.76 1.40 13.39 1.06 33.27 48.12
Non-Poor 37626 4.70 0.83 8.41 1.61 30.02 54.43
SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001.
The evidence suggests that due to the relatively smaller crop share retained by the poor
tenant households, they face a food deficit near the end of the year. As they run out of
their household stock of food grain, they are obliged to purchase grain in the market at
year end when market prices are relatively high. (Hussain, 1988)10. Such households are
then faced with the necessity of borrowing for food consumption. This is also suggested 7
by the NHDR evidence, which shows that the extremely poor households borrow for food
consumption (Hussain et.al., 2003)11
.
Poor farm households are thus placed under a double squeeze: First by the power of the
landlord, who obliges them to give up a relatively larger proportion of their crop output
as a crop share to the landlord. A second squeeze is placed by the seasonal variation in
the market price of grain, which obliges the extremely poor households to purchase a
relatively larger proportion of their food consumption requirements from the market near
the end of the production cycle, when prices are high. (A. Hussain, 2004)12
.
I.3 Adverse Changes in Tenancy Arrangements and Poverty
As the evidence suggests, since the majority of the rural poor are tenants, therefore any
deterioration in tenancy arrangements would be expected to accentuate poverty. Due to
weakening relative power position of poor tenants, tenancy arrangements have changed
adversely against them. They now have to bear a higher proportion of input costs
compared to the landlord on the tenant operated farms. The evidence shows that the
contribution of tenants to input costs (for each of the major crops) such as tractor rental13
,
hired labour, seeds and fertilizers have increased during the period 1990-91 to 2000-01.
TABLE 3
CONTRIBUTION OF TENANTS IN INPUTS
PERCENTAGES
1990-91 2000-2001
Tractor Labour Seeds Fertilizer Tractor Labour Seeds Fertilizer
Extremely Poor 36.3 13.8 24.8 26.0 43.5 28.5 31.0 31.8
Poor 29.5 18.8 22.8 24.5 41.3 30.5 34.5 34.0
Non-poor 39.8 25.8 28.8 27.3 44.5 32.8 38.8 34.5
Total 34.3 22.5 24.8 25.5 42.8 30.3 34.0 33.3
SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001. For Crop wise figures, see: Akmal Hussain et.al., UNDPPakistan
National Human Development Report 2003, op.cit., page 64, table 16.
The above evidence suggests that the adverse changes in tenancy arrangements with
respect to input contributions of the tenant have become a significant structural factor in
generating poverty. While the financial burden on the poor tenants has thus increased, 8
their lack of control over the timing water application, combined with adulterated inputs,
keeps the yield per acre of the peasant at a low level, thereby further squeezing net
incomes.
I.4 Asymmetric Markets for Inputs and Outputs
In the UNDP, Pakistan National Human Development Report 2003, it has been argued
that local elite power structures in rural areas distort markets in favour of the rich and
against the poor. The poor peasants face input and output markets where they have to pay
a higher price for their inputs and get a lower price for their outputs compared to large
farmers. The study showed that the poor peasants are losing as much as one third of their
income due to asymmetric markets (Hussain et.al., 2003)14
.
II. GOVERNANCE, INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH
In this sub-section we will show how the institutional structure of governance constrains
the provision of adequate health, education and security, which are major factors in
perpetuating poverty. We will also show how the incentive system implied in rent based
governance constrain sustained and equitable growth.
II.1 Poverty and Illness
The NHDR showed that due to inadequate diet and lack of access over safe drinking
water and sanitation facilities, 65.1 percent of the extremely poor and 55.6 percent of the
poor in the sample survey were suffering from ill health. The data also shows that the
poor respondents reporting sickness at the time of the interview had on average suffered
from their sickness for 95 days of the year15. (See table 4).
The study showed that the prevalence of disease amongst those who are slightly above
the poverty line is a major factor in pushing them into poverty. Those who are already
poor get pushed into deeper poverty as a result of loss of income due to absence from
work, and high medical costs resulting from illness. Thus the unequal access over public
health facilities and the relatively high prevalence of disease amongst the poor becomes a
structural factor that further accentuates both poverty and inequality. 9
TABLE 4
PERCENTAGE OF POOR WHO ARE SICK, NUMBER OF DAYS OF SICKNESS, TREATMENT
EXPENSES AND DISTANCE TRAVELLED FOR MEDICAL CONSULTATION [HEAD OF
HOUSEHOLD ONLY]
Economic Status Sick at the Time of
Survey (percent)
Number of Days in
Current Sickness
(Mean)
Treatment
Expenses
(Rs.)
Percent of Patients
Travelling over 6
Kms.
Extremely Poor 65.1 94.9 1885 49.4
Poor 55.6 27.4 497 29.5
SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001.
II.2 Education, Poverty and Growth
The relatively low levels of literacy, high school enrolment rates and the poor quality of
both school education as well as higher education in Pakistan compared to other South
Asian countries indicates the low priority given to education. This is understandable in a
country where allocation of public resources and the institutional framework for
translating them into outcomes are determined by a ruling elite in which the military, the
bureaucracy and the landlords have been dominant factions. Within this power structure
there is greater priority for expenditures on the military, bureaucracy, and transfer of
public resources as rents to various strata of the elite and its dependents. Building an
institutional framework for higher education based on high quality research is also not a
high priority. Education requires an environment of freedom to pose and pursue new
questions and to engage in critical thinking. This is inimical to a rent based power
structure that relies on authoritarian rule whether in a military or civilian form.
Although the literacy rate has increased sharply from 46 percent in 1999 to 54 percent in
2006, the gender gap remains high (23 percentage points) and has not changed
significantly over the period16. The gross primary school enrolment rate at about 70
percent has remained unchanged over the last two decades inspite of the multi billion
dollar Social Action Programme during the 1990s. At the same time almost 25 percent of
the total population (over 40 million) consists of adult illiterates. Due to the relatively
low school enrolment rates the number of adult illiterates is expected to rise during the 10
coming decade, thereby increasing poverty even if greater employment opportunities
become available. In Pakistan, 91.6 percent (Majid, 1997)17 of the labour force is
unskilled, with low productivity and poor adaptability to technical change. This
constitutes a significant structural constraint to both growth and poverty reduction.
The survey evidence in the Pakistan National Human Development Report shows that
one of the key factors that can pull a poor household out of poverty is whether or not the
family has a second earner. The data indicates that the magnitude of the second earner’s
income depends on the level of education (Hussain et.al., 2003)18
.
The poor coverage and quality of school education and vocational training in Pakistan
thus constitutes a significant structural constraint to growth as well as poverty reduction.
The extremely poor quality of higher education in most universities of Pakistan and the
control of many of them by obscurantist and coercive religious groups is as much a
constraint to equitable growth as it is to building an enlightened, pluralistic and
democratic polity.
II.3 Poverty, Justice and Citizens’ Security
The poor live in localities both rural and urban, which are inadequately policed and in
case of theft or violence against their person the cost of seeking redress through the
judicial system is in most cases unaffordable and where undertaken, the expenses in
terms of time and money, lock the poor into permanent debt. This is another factor that
engenders endemic poverty, reinforces inequality and thereby constrains economic
growth. [See Table 5].
TABLE 5
FREQUENCY OF DISPUTES, RESOLUTION AND COST OF RESOLUTION BY ECONOMIC
STATUS (CASES REPORTING DISPUTES ONLY)
ECONOMIC STATUS
DISTRIBUTION OF
REPORTED DISPUTES
(%)
AMOUNT SPENT ON
MEDIATION (MEAN)
PERCENT OF
REPORTED
DISPUTES
RESOLVED
Extremely Poor 17.1 Rs. 18,333 38.5%
Poor 48.7 Rs. 12,074 59.5%
Non Poor 34.2 Rs. 18,264 80.8%
Total/Average 100 Rs. 15,123 63.2%
Source: NHDR/PIDE Poor Communities Survey 2001. 11
II.4 Low Domestic Savings Rate, Taxation and Growth
Given the rent based governance model in Pakistan the business elite enjoys various
forms of financial support from the government (subsidies, cheap credit, import
protection, tax exemptions). Therefore, it is not surprising that entrepreneurs (many of
whom are also landlords) following the tradition of the landed elite engage in
conspicuous consumption and tend to have a low propensity to save.
The domestic savings rate in Pakistan has historically been below the investment rate,
thereby creating a persistent savings gap that has induced a growing national debt
particularly during high GDP growth periods. (For example, the average annual domestic
savings as a percentage of GDP during the period 2001 to 2007 was 16.5 percent. By
contrast the investment rate required to sustain the target growth rate of 7.5% with an
ICOR of 4, is 30%)19. The consequent debt servicing problem has now become a
constraint to growth just as it did in the Ayub period in the 1960s and in the BenazirNawaz
period in the 1990s. The low savings rate and the consequent dependence on
foreign inflows is a major factor in the stop-go pattern of GDP growth in Pakistan’s
history. (For a detailed discussion of this phenomenon, see, A. Hussain, 2008, chapter
2)20
.
The high debt servicing requirements resulting from a tendency of the rent seeking elite
to consume rather than save, and at the same time avoid direct taxes, has obliged
successive governments to charge high and increasing rates of indirect taxes. An earlier
study on the increase in the incidence of the tax burden, shows that the percentage
increase in the tax burden as a percentage of income was highest at 6.8% for the lowest
income group (less than Rs.700/- per month) and lowest at -4.3 percent for the highest
income group, (over Rs.4500/- per month). The evidence shows that over time the tax
burden for the poor increased and for the rich declined21. Thus the rent based governance
model and its incentive systems have induced a pattern of elite consumption and
government tax policy that further reinforces income inequality in the growth process. 12
II.5 Institutions, Export Structure and Growth
Pakistan as it emerged in 1947, not only inherited various institutions of the state with
their underlying structures of power, but also rent seeking and risk averse behavioural
proclivities of the economic elite. In the post independence period the inherited
governance model, the power structures, the associated institutional framework, and the
tradition bound nature of the industrial elite, had as great an impact on government
economic policy as on the pattern of investment and export growth.
Pakistan’s slow export growth and the consequent perennial pressures on the balance of
payments constitute a structural constraint to sustaining high GDP growth. Slow export
growth is rooted in the rent seeking nature of the industrial elite and its failure to
diversify into non-traditional high value added exports. Even after 60 years of industrial
growth, the percentage of total investment going into textiles and related goods has not
declined. (It was 41 percent in 1964-65 and 44 percent in 1990-91). In terms of output, 80
percent of Pakistan’s manufactured exports consist of textiles and clothing compared to
12 percent for the developing countries group and 6.5 percent for the world as a whole22
.
The persistence of Pakistan’s textile based export structure is an important factor
constraining overall export growth. This is because of a changing composition of demand
in the global market where the world trade in textiles is growing at a much slower rate
than non-traditional manufactured exports.
Pakistan’s textile industry which has remained at the lower end of the value added range
emerged in the 1960s as a result of large government subsidies. The institutional structure
of policy created disincentives to innovation, productivity increase and export
diversification. By the 1990s the structure of state support to industry was substantially
dismantled. However even then, as late as 1990-91 as much as 7 percent of GDP was
transferred by the government to industrialists in the form of subsidies (Kemal, 1999)23
.
Diversification of industry into higher value added exports was constrained by
government patronage on the one hand and on the other, the lack of risk taking dynamism
amongst most industrialists. 13
II.6 Official Corruption and Poverty
Poverty and inequality increased rapidly during the 1990s due to the decline in GDP
growth, coupled with a decline in employment elasticities, labour productivity, and real
wages in both the agriculture and the industrial sectors. (A. Hussain, 2004)24. In the
subsequent period 1998-99 to 2004-05, while GDP growth accelerated sharply there was
no significant poverty reduction. (See Table 7). This proposition is also established in the
recent work of Talat Anwar25 and H. Gazdar, A. Sayeed and A. Hussain26. At the same
time unemployment as well as inflation rates, particularly food inflation, increased
sharply. The economic burden on the poor has intensified further due to inadequacies in
two major aspects of governance:
(i) Inefficient delivery mechanisms for translating development expenditure into
improved health, sanitation, education, services and access over justice for the
poor. Consequently, the disproportionate shortages of these services for the poor
compared to the rich, have deprived them of an important redistributive
mechanism in the economy.
(ii) During the 1990s corruption in government, had a significant adverse impact on
economic growth and poverty27. During the period of the Musharraf government
even though GDP growth accelerated widespread corruption persisted. Corruption
levels in this period were even higher than in South Asian countries such as Sri
Lanka, India and Nepal. (Talat Anwar, 2006)28. According to the Transparency
International Report (December 6, 2007), during the last two years corruptions
levels increased sharply. For example the percentage of people in the all Pakistan
sample, who paid bribes for obtaining services doubled to over 30 percent
compared to 15 percent in the year 2006. The report places Pakistan among the
top 10 countries which are most affected by bribery.
Widespread corruption in government contributes to constraining growth and
increasing poverty in three ways: (a) the rising magnitude of corruption over time
and at different levels of decision making in the government is a major factor in
the uncertain policy environment and a constraint to estimating accurate project 14
feasibilities. This would be expected to constrict investment, GDP growth and
employment; (b) the transfer of resources from entrepreneurs to politicians and
government officials results in a misallocation of national resources and a lower
level of productive investment and hence GDP growth, than would be the case in
the absence of such corruption. (c) the financial cost of individual projects
increases, thereby simultaneously inducing slower GDP growth for given levels
of investment and also reducing the employment elasticities with respect to
investment. (d) To the extent that the poor are obliged to pay bribes for public
services while in many cases the affluent with political influence may not have to
pay bribes, means that the distribution of real income between the rich and the
poor is worsened by the mode of provisioning of public services.
II.7 Institutional Factors in Slow and Unstable Crop Sector Growth29
In agriculture the average annual growth rate of major crops has declined from 3.34%
during the eighties to 2.38% in the nineties. At the same time, the frequency of negative
growth years in some of the major crops has increased. This has accentuated the process
of poverty creation: In a year of negative growth (i.e. bad harvest) the small farmers
operating at the margin, have to borrow for consumption requirements and go into debt.
In the following season, in the absence of an investible surplus, they are unable to
reconstitute the production cycle and hence slip into poverty. Thus the instability of crop
sector growth and the increased frequency of negative growth years becomes a structural
factor in poverty creation. Underlying this phenomenon are five major institutional
constraints:
(a) Reduced water availability at the farm gate due to poor maintenance of the
irrigation system and low irrigation efficiencies of about 37 percent. While the
availability of irrigation water has been reduced, the requirement of water at
the farm level has increased due to increased deposits of salts on the top soil
and the consequent need for leaching30. The consequent large water deficit
means that the farmers even in the irrigated areas are dependent on rain fall.
Given the vicissitudes of weather particularly due to global warming, (which 15
has caused wide variation in the timing, location and quantum of rain fall) rain
does not always fall in the right quantity at the right time for the water deficit
farmers. Consequently, there is greater instability in crop sector output than
before. (Akmal Hussain, 1999)31
.
(b) What makes improved efficiency of irrigation even more important is that the
extensive margin of irrigated acreage has been reached, so the future
agricultural growth will have to rely on improving the efficiency of water use
and other inputs. Thus the rehabilitation of Pakistan's irrigation system for
improving irrigation efficiency has become a crucial policy challenge for
sustainable agriculture growth.
(c) It is well known that high yielding varieties of seeds gradually lose their
potency through re-use, changing micro structure of soils, and changing
ecology of micro organisms in the top soil. In wheat for example the average
age of seeds in Pakistan is 11 years compared to 7 years for all developing
countries (A. Hussain, 1999)32. Therefore, breeding of more vigorous seed
varieties adapted to local environmental conditions, and their diffusion
amongst farmers through an effective research and extension programme is
necessary33
.
(d) A new dimension to the imperative of improving research capability in the
crop sector is indicated by the possibility of declining yields per acre related
with global warming. Given the sensitivity of wheat seed to temperature
increase, even a 2-degree centigrade increase in average summer temperatures
could mean an absolute yield decline of between 10 to 16 percent during the
21st century. (Qureshi, Ata and Iglesias, 1992)34. With a 2.8 percent
population growth, even a decline of 5 percent in yield per acre associated
with global warming, could mean serious food deficits and high food inflation
rates for Pakistan, with relatively greater adverse consequences for the poor.
It is, therefore, necessary to develop heat resistant varieties of food grains. 16
(e) One of the most important constraints to sustainable growth in the crop sector
is the degradation of soils, resulting from improper agricultural practices such
as: (i) lack of crop rotation and the resultant loss of humus in the top soil; (ii)
stripping of top soil and resultant loss of fertility associated with over grazing;
(iii) water erosion along hill sides and river banks due to cutting down of trees
and depletion of natural vegetation. According to one estimate, over 11
million hectares have been affected by water erosion and 5 million hectares by
wind erosion. (Alim Mian and Yasin Mirza, 1993)35
.
II.8 Institutional Constraints to Growth in the Large Scale Manufacturing Sector
The growth rate of the large scale manufacturing sector was 12.43% in the period
1959/60 to 1969/70, and fell to 2.21% in the period 1996/97 to 1999/2000. In the
subsequent four years the growth of this sector accelerated sharply, but has begun to
decline again in the last two years. The factors underlying the tendency for large scale
manufacturing to decline are as follows:
(a) A fundamental structural constraint to industrial growth as indeed the underlying
factor in slow export growth, is the failure to diversify exports. The large scale
manufacturing output, particularly exports are concentrated in the traditional low
value added end of textiles.
(b) A changed pattern of global demand for industrial products with a shift towards
higher value added and knowledge intensive products. Pakistan’s industrial
structure was not positioned to respond quickly to these changed market
conditions.
(c) An erosion of the domestic framework within which investment and growth is
sustained. This includes: (i) a continued threat to the life and property of citizens
due to the persistent poor law and order situation; (ii) high electricity tariffs and
relatively high interest rates; (iii) lack of trained professionals especially in the
high skill sector; (iv) an inadequate technological base through which industry
can respond in a flexible way to changing patterns of demand; (v) an adverse
policy environment in the past within which tariff and export incentives were 17
distorted against those entrepreneurs who were seeking to improve quality and
productivity for export growth; (vi) dumping of smuggled, poor quality and
extremely low priced imported goods which are in many cases counterfeit copies
of branded Pakistani manufactured goods.
III. POLICIES FOR ADDRESSING THE STRUCTURAL CONSTRAINTS TO
GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION
In the preceding section of this paper we have identified some of the structural factors
underlying endemic poverty and unstable growth. In this section we will indicate briefly
the policies that can be undertaken to overcome the structural constraints to sustained and
equitable growth.
III.1 Empowering the Poor for Market Access
The evidence shows that asymmetric markets and local power structures constitute
structural factors in persistent poverty. They siphon off as much as one third of the actual
incomes of the poor, deprive them of their potential savings and keep their productivity
and incomes at a low level. A pro poor policy must address these structural factors if
poverty is to be overcome on a sustainable basis. Better access for the poor over the
markets for labour, land, agricultural inputs and outputs, means changing the balance of
power in favour of the poor at the local level. This requires facilitating the emergence of
autonomous organisations of the poor, particularly poor women at the village, Union
Council, Tehsil and district levels. It also means enabling the poor to access credit,
training, and technical support for increased employment, productivity, and incomes.
III.2 Land for the Landless
One of the most important factors in endemic poverty in the rural areas (where the
majority of Pakistan’s poor reside), is the fact that millions of households do not have
access over land or their ownership of this productive asset is less than the critical level
required for subsistence. The data show that the poor peasants where they own land have
on average two acres while the bigger farmers are able to rent in additional land the poor
ones either rent out their small holdings for a pittance or are obliged to sell their land 18
altogether: As many as 76.5 percent of the extremely poor farmers and 38.9 percent of
the poor farmers sold their land over the last 10 years. (Hussain et.al. 2003)36. The
evidence shows that the poor had to sell their land for urgent consumption needs related
with health expenditures, crop failures and marriages. Thus lack of access over this vital
productive asset is an important structural factor in endemic poverty.
In order to alleviate the problem of landlessness it is proposed that the government launch
a programme of allotting state owned land to the landless as part of its overall strategy of
growth with poverty reduction.
However, it is important to recognize that providing ownership of land to the landless is a
necessary but not a sufficient condition for alleviating their poverty. Enabling the
landless to make the transferred land cultivable, to actually settle on the new land and to
achieve a sustainable increase in their income, productivity and savings are equally
important factors in making the scheme successful37
.
III.3 Mainstreaming the Poor through Equity Stakes
An institutional change that could bring the poor into the mainstream of the market
economy could be to establish professionally managed public limited companies in which
the poor have a substantial equity stake. This concept was first propounded by Professor
Rehman Sobhan and successfully tried out in the diversification process of the Grameen
Bank in Bangladesh. It was also tried out in India by Dr. Kurien who set up the Amul
(originally a cooperative) which is entirely owned by the poor and is now one of the
largest manufacturers of milk products in the corporate sector in South Asia.
In the Pakistan case there may be considerable potential for developing livestock and
milk production by the rural poor and providing these products to large private sector
corporations for the manufacture and export of milk and meat products. These private
sector corporations which would be buying their inputs from the poor could also be
owned substantially by the poor. The equity stake to the poor could be initially achieved
through the provision of loans which could be paid back from the dividends of the
corporations. Similar public limited companies owned by the poor and run by high 19
quality professionals could also be established in key main stream sectors of the economy
such as energy, telecommunications and electronics.
III.4 Health Policy for the Poor
In the preceding section shows that illness is a major factor that pushes people into
poverty therefore improved nutrition and health conditions are important for poverty
reduction. Improving the nutrition, preventive hygiene, provision of safe drinking water,
improving the service delivery of basic health units, and improved diagnostic and
treatment capabilities of Tehsil and District Hospitals are urgent imperatives to deal with
the crisis of health and poverty.
III.5 Education for Development
As we have argued, education is a major factor that pulls people out of poverty. It is also
perhaps the single most important factor that can induce sustained and equitable growth.
Education can achieve this objective by providing equality of opportunity for productive
employment to all the people not just the elite. The strategic aims of an education policy
would be: (a) Improve the coverage and quality of schools, particularly for girls. (b)
Skilling the labour force by establishing a network of industry specific vocational training
institutes in every province. (c) Capacity building of selected universities to enable them
to conduct research and teaching at world class standards.
III.6 Combating Corruption
In the preceding section-II we have argued that two of the most important governance
factors that prevent sustained high growth and rapid poverty reduction are the persistent
high levels of corruption and inefficient delivery mechanisms for the provision of public
services. Addressing these issues requires establishing new institutions at different levels
of governance.
The institutional structure that makes corruption endemic, also increases transaction costs
and thereby constrains specialization, productivity and growth. Therefore, a policy of
combating corruption through the establishment of institutions in state and civil society, 20
would be important drivers of change for development. In this context six new
institutions could help control corruption:
An independent judiciary with adequate resources and judicial officers to provide
access to justice at every tier of governance and in every region: national,
provincial and district levels.
An independent and constitutionally mandated structure of ombudsman’s offices
at the district, tehsil and union council levels to listen to and rectify public
complaints about the equitable provision of public services. At the same time the
ombudsman’s offices at each tier, would hear and rectify citizens’ complaints
about corruption and misuse of office by government functionaries.
Citizens’ Protection Committees at the mohallah and village levels where
complaints about the provision of public services and against corrupt officials can
be registered and systematically taken up38
.
An independent media equipped with adequate investigative reporting capabilities
to independently report corruption cases and monitor the performance of
government departments with respect to the provision of public services39
.
An independent Federal Bureau Statistics (FBS) that directly reports to the
Parliament through a Parliamentary Committee on Policy Impact Assessment.
The FBS would be tasked to conduct periodic surveys on the incidence of
poverty, gender specific employment, inflation, productivity and real wages. The
FBS would also be tasked to provide survey based data on the quality and
coverage of services such as health, sanitation, hygienic drinking water, education
and vocational training40
.
The bilateral as well as multilateral Donors in Pakistan could establish a Multidonor
Transparency Support Unit (MTSU) whose task would be to determine the
extent to which donor funds have achieved the purposes for which they had been
provided to both government as well as civil society organizations. 21
III.7 Institutional Policies for Stabilizing Crop Sector Growth
Institutional change for improved irrigation efficiency. The poor maintenance and
operation of the canal irrigation system that is a major constraint to both the rate
of crop sector growth, is associated with both a decline in the efficiency of the
irrigation department as well as inadequate funding. Given the lack of motivation,
management capability and funding, a restructuring of the role, functioning and
organization of the irrigation department may be necessary. Therefore the
required policy initiative is to develop more cost effective and decentralized
institutional structure, involving local communities in the operation and
maintenance of canals and water courses. In this context autonomous community
organizations of water users along individual distributaries need to be formed and
then take responsibility for both revenue collection and maintenance.
Policies for improved seeds, agriculture research and diffusion:
Seeds, Agriculture Research and Diffusion. The breeding of more
vigorous seed varieties adapted to local environmental conditions and their
diffusion amongst farmers is required through an effective research and
extension program.
The existing institutional framework for agriculture research suffers from
a proliferation of research institutes, which are inadequately funded, often
lack professional expertise, proper equipment and the research
environment necessary to produce significant results. Finally, there is
considerable overlapping of research responsibilities across institutes.
Consequently, research has by and large failed to produce operationally
usable results much less increase input efficiency41
.
No comments:
Post a Comment