1
Preliminary Draft
February 20, 2010
THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS AND SOUTH ASIA
By
Dr. Akmal Hussain,
Distinguished Professor,
Beaconhouse National University
INTRODUCTION
What began as a financial crisis in 2008 rapidly metastasized into a global economic
crisis that pushed the world economy into the deepest recession since the Great
Depression of the 1930s. In this paper we will examine the origins and nature of this
crisis in the context of the dynamics of world capitalism, indicate the policy challenges in
the process of recovery and analyze its impact on South Asia.
I. STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND FRAGILITY OF THE FINANCIAL
SPHERE
In the process of its growth the world economy has undergone a structural change in the
post war period in terms of two important features:
(i) The dominant form of the production unit of goods and services that
emerged in the post war period was the large multinational corporation
(MNC) in contrast to the large national corporation in the late 19th century
and the small firm in the late 18th century.1
The MNCs were not only able
to sell goods and services on a global scale but were able to achieve
internationalization in their production processes, such that different
components of a particular good could be manufactured in their facilities
in different countries to take advantage of country specific resource
1
For a more detailed analysis of Growth and Structural Change in the Global Economy since the
Industrial Revolution, See: Akmal Hussain, Imperialism, in, Syed B. Hussain (ed.), Encyclopedia
of Capitalism, Volume-II, Golson Books Limited, New York, 2004. 2
endowments. This laid the basis of an unprecedented growth in
productivity, and profits. Given the problem of investing these profits
within the sphere of production, due to demand constraints, profits from
the sphere of production began to flow into the financial sphere2
.
(ii) Within two decades in the second half of the 20th century (1963 to 1985)
the relative weight of the financial sphere in the world economy changed
dramatically: It became larger than the sphere of production, in contrast to
the preceding two centuries when the sphere of production far outweighed
the financial sphere. As Table 1 shows, in 1964 international banking was
only about one-tenth of the value of the international trade in goods and
services. During the next two decades the financial sphere grew about
twelve times faster than the sphere of production. By 1985, international
banking had become greater than the value of international trade in
manufactured goods and services.
The diffusion of computers to the household level and the internet associated with the
‘I.T. revolution’ gave millions of individuals and firms the capacity to buy and sell stocks
at the touch of a button. At the same time the inter linkages of stock markets across the
world, and the crafting of new financial products such as derivatives, laid the basis of
explosive growth in what had by the late 20th century become a globalized banking
system. It is not surprising therefore that the financial sphere which was only about 11
percent of the sphere of production had by 1985 become greater than the size of the
production sphere. In the next two decades the financial sphere continued to grow
rapidly, although at a slower pace than in the preceding two decades, so that the size of
this sphere had reached US $ 214,424 billion by the year 2008. (See Table 1).
The emergence of finance as the dominant sphere imparted to the global economy a new
fragility. Banks and finance companies could rapidly devise a wide range of new
2
P. A. Baran and P.M. Sweezy, Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and
Social Order, Monthly Review Press, New York, 1966. 3
financial products and sell them in the global market at a speed that would be
unimaginable in earlier decades.
II. RISK, MARKET FAILURE AND CRISIS
The Nature of Systemic Risk and the Problem of Measurement. There is an important
dimension to the tendency for crisis in a finance dominated global economy: The weak
institutional framework combined with the nature of risk measurement in economic
science. The dynamics of the financial sphere produced escalating systemic risk, and yet
it was inherently difficult to measure it, let alone the incapability of the market to provide
a feedback mechanism for it. While the institutional framework and the state of economic
science allowed measurement of individual risk it did not enable measurement of
systemic risk. As Michael Spence has pointed out, in a situation where individual risks
were positively correlated, systemic risk was difficult to estimate3
. This is because the
estimation of risk at the aggregate level of the system, in probability theory, is based on a
particular distribution of individual risk. If, as happened in the case of the current crisis,
the distribution of individual risk is changing then, it becomes difficult to accurately
model systemic risk4
.
Financial Fragility and Dynamics of the Crisis. The basis of fragility in the global
financial system lay in two fundamental features of the new financial edifice:
(i) The new financial products were priced by financial experts on the basis of
risk estimates drawn from mathematical probability which were not
transparent to the buyers. This asymmetry of information between producers
and buyers of financial products created a tendency for individuals and
organizations to undertake overly risky investments without being aware of it.
This gave a fragility to the global financial edifice.
3
Michael Spence, Agenda for the Next Few Months, chapter in, What G20 Leaders must do to
Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial System, VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR, 2009.
4
Ibid. 4
(ii) What made the fragility acute was the fact that many of these financial
products such as sub prime mortgage, debt bonds and risk insurance while
appearing individually distinct products, were actually interlinked and hence
created escalating risk at the systemic level.
It is these two features of asymmetric information at both the micro and the macro levels
that gave to the global financial system the potential for market failure within an
inadequate regulatory framework. Spiraling production and sale of derivatives, with
multiplying systemic risks that were unknown to the individual investors, created a time
bomb that could threaten the global financial system and thereby the real economy. The
evidence shows that every major financial entity was highly levered and at the same time
held potentially toxic assets. This fact exposed all the major financial organizations in the
world to extreme financial distress5
. When the time bomb exploded some of the most
important banks and finance companies suffered simultaneous and major damage which
brought the financial and economic system of the world into the most serious crisis in a
century.
III. THE IMPACT OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMIC CRISIS ON SOUTH ASIA
The crisis in the sphere of finance rapidly permeated into the sphere of the real economy
resulting in negative GDP growth rates and sharply rising unemployment levels in
Europe, the US and Japan. Unlike the Western world, China and India did not suffer
economic contraction in absolute terms but nevertheless their GDP growth rates which
were over 8 percent in earlier years declined significantly. The deepening recession in the
rich countries was associated with a sharp decline in demand for the exports of the South
Asian countries, combined with a sharp decline in foreign investment. Consequently,
South Asian countries suffered from the globalized recession, although the magnitude of
the adverse effect in individual countries varied, depending on the degree of vulnerability
of the particular country and the sate of its economy at the time of the global recession.
5
Michael Spence, Agenda for the Next Few Months, chapter in, What G20 Leaders must do to
Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial System, VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR, 2009. 5
It is at this time of crisis that the lack of integration of the South Asian economies is
manifesting itself in terms of the relatively intense adverse impact on individual
economies. Intra regional trade in South Asia is only 5 percent of the trade of South
Asian countries with the rest of the world. If there had been a greater integration of the
South Asian economies, the regional home market would have substantially cushioned
the decline in global demand for South Asian exports. As it was South Asian countries in
most cases following the global economic recession suffered a sharp decline in GDP
growth rates, increased poverty, worsening fiscal and balance of payments deficits,
increased inflation and pressures on the exchange rate. These effects were exacerbated by
the fact that South Asian economies were already suffering from inflationary as well as
balance of payments pressures associated with the oil price shock and the food price
shock that had occurred in the months preceding the onset of global recession.
In this section we will briefly discuss the country specific impact in South Asia with
respect to key economic variables, following the global recession. Table 2 shows foreign
direct investment following the global economic crisis fell in each South Asian country.
The sharpest decline occurred in the case of Sri Lanka where foreign investment although
at a low level to start with declined by 42 percent in the year 2008. This was followed by
India which had the largest foreign direct investment inflows at the outset, suffered a 36
percent decline. In the case of Bangladesh it declined by 18 percent. In the case of
Pakistan while foreign investment did not decline initially it has fallen sharply in the last
seven months by as much as 35 percent.
Declining GDP growth rates in South Asia led to a slow down in government revenues.
At the same time public expenditure increased as governments in South Asia attempted to
provide succor to the poor as well as to the declining industry. Consequently fiscal
deficits increased sharply in each of the countries of South Asia except Sri Lanka (See
Table 3).
There was a sharp decline in exports in South Asian countries following the global
recession. However given their composition, import expenditures did not decline
proportionately with the decline in GDP growth rates. Consequently the current account 6
of the balance of payments worsened in each South Asian country as seen in Table 4. The
sharpest increase in the current account deficit occurred in the case of India where this
figure as a percentage of GDP doubled from -1.5 percent in the year 2007 to 3 percent in
the year 2008. Pakistan was close behind with this figure increasing from -4.8 percent in
2007 to -8.4 percent in 2008, Sri Lanka’s current account deficit increased from -4.5 to -
7.1 in the same period. Bangladesh which had a current account surplus in the year 2007
merely suffered a decline in this surplus, which fell from 1.4 percent in 2007 to 0.9
percent in 2008.
Poverty and inequality in South Asian countries has increased following the adverse
impact of global recession on South Asian GDP growth rates. At the same time balance
of payments and fiscal pressures have severely constrained the ability of governments to
address the problem of mass poverty. In the years ahead this will create stresses on state
structures, and the process of building democracies, particularly in a situation where
some of the South Asian countries face internal social conflict.
IV. ECONOMIC RECOVERY AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE: AN
AGENDA FOR ACTION
The path to recovery in the global economy requires careful selection of policy
instruments and precise timing and coordination of policy initiatives by countries.
Equally important, reducing the vulnerability of the world economy to acute crises in the
future will require changes in the institutional regulatory framework of the world’s
financial system. The following issues in this context require urgent attention:
1. Leaders across the world need to unite against unilateral actions such as
protectionist measures which could push the world into a deeper recession.
This is particularly important because in a situation of rising unemployment
and fluctuating exchange rates, there is a temptation within individual
countries to raise import barriers. As Dani Rodrik has pointed out the 7
experience of the Great Depression of the 1930s shows that such protectionist
measures are counter productive as they deepen the crisis6
.
2. As the economies of the Western world and Japan which had earlier suffered
negative growth rates have shown signs of recovery in the last quarter, these
countries are considering the gradual withdrawal of the stimulus packages
initiated earlier. Yet recovery in the Western countries is still fragile. It is not
yet clear whether this recovery can be sustained without a government
stimulus and by private sector investment and consumer demand. For
example, the rising GDP figures of the US in the fourth quarter of the 2009
(annualized output growth of 5.7 percent) may be misleading because firms
were merely re-building their stocks. With restrained consumer demand and
underutilized productive capacity of firms, it is unlikely that new investment
will take place quickly to sustain an economic recovery. In Europe also the
prospects of a sustained recovery are grim as the earlier crisis of banks has
been replaced by the danger of sovereign defaults by countries such as
Greece, Portugal and Spain.
While there is a continued need to stimulate the economy in the West, the
choice of policy instruments has to be carefully considered. The recent
massive stimulus packages have increased the fiscal deficits in Europe four
fold, to an average of 9 percent of GDP. Similarly public debt has reached
unsustainable level in rich countries, increasing from 80 percent of GDP to
almost 100 percent of GDP in two years. The IMF estimates that it will
increase further to 120 percent by 20157
. Therefore the earlier unlimited
liquidity facility offered on an emergency basis to banks could be withdrawn.
At the same time the composition of public expenditure needs to be changed
towards generating revenue streams for the government in the future.
Economic stimulus in the years ahead will therefore have to rely less on
6
Dani Rodrik, Making International Finance Safe for the World Economy – Not the other way
around: What should the G20 Communique say?, chapter in, What G20 Leaders must do to
Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial System, VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR, 2009.
7
The Economist, February 13 to 19, 2010. Pages 73 to 75. 8
government largesse to collapsing firms and more on using the interest rate
and continued tax cuts to stimulate investment and demand.
3. In the case of India and China where GDP growth rates have largely
weathered the crisis, there may be a need to take early remedial measures (as
China and India are doing) to prevent over heating and the build up of
inflationary pressures in the economy. This is being done by increasing the
reserve requirements of banks and restricting credit. At the same time an
institutional framework needs to be put into place to prevent speculative
investment in real estate.
4. The earlier ideological belief that markets are self regulating and always
deliver efficient outcomes, needs to be put to rest. There is a need to recognize
as we have argued in this paper, that the very nature of risk and the
asymmetric information in markets creates a systemic risk of market failure.
Therefore there is a need to establish a new regulatory framework for the
global financial system. The aim should be to provide strong disincentives to
individuals and firms to being carried away by escalating speculative risk.
Perhaps early warning systems need to put into place by the regulatory
authority. At the same time there is a need to carefully consider Dani Rodrik’s
suggestion: The rules that govern financial globalization need to be redesigned
to ensure that finance serves its primary goals: allocate savings to
high return projects and enhance risk sharing without leading to crises8
.
8
Dani Rodrik, Making International Finance Safe for the World Economy – Not the other way
around: What should the G20 Communiqué say?, chapter in, What G20 Leaders must do to
Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial System, VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR, 2009. 9
TABLE 1
INTERNATIONAL BANKING, ECONOMIC ACTIVITY, AND
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
AMOUNT
(BILLIONS OF DOLLARS AT CURRENT PRICES AND
EXCHANGE RATES)
1964 1972 1980 1983 1985 2008**
GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT
(WORLD)*
1,605 3,336 10,172 10,140 12,825 --
INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN
GOODS AND SERVICES
(WORLD)¤
188 463 2,150 1,986 2,190 --
INTERNATIONAL
BANKING¤¤
20 208 1,559 2,253 2,598 214,424
SOURCE: RALPH C. BRYANT, INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL
INTERMEDIATION (WASHINGTON, D.C.: THE BROOKINGS
INSTITUTION, 1987), P.22.
SOURCE**: IMF, GLOBAL FINANCIAL STABILITY REPORT, OCT. 2009,
Table 3.
NOTE¤: WORLD, EXCEPT EASTERN EUROPE.
NOTE¤¤: BANK ASSETS, BONDS AND EQUITIES (GLOBAL) 10
TABLE 2
FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT
Us $ Million
Country 2006 2007 2008
Bangladesh 743 793 650
India 21,991 32,327 20,700
Pakistan 3,450 5,026 5,078
Sri Lanka 451 548 313
Sources: (1) Asian Development Outlook, 2009.
(2) Cited in: Rashid Amjad and Musleh ud Din, Economic and Social Impact
of Global Financial Crisis: Implications for Macroeconomic and
Development Policies in South Asia (Preliminary Draft), PIDE, Islamabad
October 2009. 11
TABLE 3
FISCAL DEFICIT AS PERCENT OF GDP
Country 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Bangladesh -3.2 -3.3 -3.2 -3.2 -4.7
India -7.5 -6.7 -6.4 -5.4 -6.0
Pakistan -2.9 -3.3 -4.3 -4.3 -7.4
Sri Lanka -7.9 -8.4 -8.0 -7.7 -6.8
Sources: (1) Asian Development Outlook, 2009.
(2) Cited in: Rashid Amjad and Musleh ud Din, Economic and Social Impact
of Global Financial Crisis: Implications for Macroeconomic and
Development Policies in South Asia (Preliminary Draft), PIDE, Islamabad
October 2009. 12
TABLE 4
CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCE AS PERCENT OF GDP
Country 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Bangladesh 0.3 -0.9 1.3 1.4 0.9 0.2
India -0.4 -1.2 -1.1 -1.5 -3 -1.5
Pakistan 1.3 -1.6 -4 -4.8 -8.4 -6
Sri Lanka -3.1 -2.7 -5.3 -4.5 -7.1 -7.5
Sources: (1) Asian Development Outlook, 2009.
(2) Cited in: Rashid Amjad and Musleh ud Din, Economic and Social Impact
of Global Financial Crisis: Implications for Macroeconomic and
Development Policies in South Asia (Preliminary Draft), PIDE, Islamabad
October 2009. 13
REFERENCES
1. Baran, P.A. and Sweezy, P.M. 1966. Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the
American Economic and Social Order, Monthly Review Press, New York.
2. Hussain, Akmal. 2004. Imperialism, in, Syed B. Hussain (ed.), Encyclopedia of
Capitalism, Volume-II, Golson Books Limited, New York.
3. Rodrik, Dani. 2009. Making International Finance Safe for the World Economy –
Not the other way around: What should the G20 Communique Say?, chapter in,
What G20 Leaders must do to Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial
System, VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR.
4. Spence, Michael. 2009. Agenda for the Next Few Months, chapter in, What G20
Leaders must do to Stabilize our Economy and fix the Financial System,
VoxEU.org Publication, CEPR.
5. The Economist, February 13 to 19, 2010.
No comments:
Post a Comment