Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 1
Published in, Rashid Amjad and Shahid Javed Burki (ed),
Pakistan: Moving the Economy Forward, Lahore School of Economics, Lahore, 2013
Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory
Development
Akmal Hussain*
1. Introduction
This chapter provides a new perspective, located in institutional
economics, on the nature of the structural constraints to achieving
sustained economic growth in Pakistan and overcoming poverty. It argues
that the fundamental factor underlying the failure so far to embark on the
process of sustained economic growth is the economy’s rent-based
institutional structure and associated patron–client-based governance
model.
The institutional structure generates rents for a small coalition of
elites by restricting competition and excluding the majority of people from
the process of saving, investment, and high-wage employment. The
consequent narrow base of economic growth is unequal; it is also incapable
of being sustained because of lack of incentives for competitive efficiency
and innovation on one hand and a low savings rate and export growth on
the other. This chapter argues that sustainable economic growth can be
achieved through an institutional change whereby the process of saving,
investment, productivity increase, and income generation can be broadbased
to include the poor and the middle classes.
Section 2 critically examines the neoliberal view that markets are
self-regulating and necessarily produce efficient outcomes. Section 3
analyzes the institutional factors underlying the pattern of economic
growth, endemic poverty, and slow growth in both export-based
manufacturing and agriculture. Section 4 argues that elite-dominated
* The author is Distinguished Professor of Economics at Forman Christian College University, and
a member of the governing board of the South Asia Centre for Policy Studies. 2 Akmal Hussain
power structures at the local level make markets as well as the provision of
public services asymmetric with respect to the rich and the poor. Some of
the main institutional factors underlying the asymmetry of markets and the
provision of public services such as health, education, and justice are
examined briefly. Section 5 presents an alternative approach: creating new
institutions through which poverty reduction can be built into the structure
of the economic growth process to make it both equitable and sustainable.
Section 6 discusses one of the dimensions of this institutional initiative—
participatory development—in the context of the nature of poverty and the
processes through which the creative energies of the poor can be
harnessed. In this new growth process, the poor and the middle classes
become active subjects rather than merely passive recipients of an
uncertain “trickle-down” effect.
2. A Conceptual Note: Are Markets Necessarily Efficient?
Over the last four decades, the view that markets necessarily
deliver efficient outcomes and are self-regulating gained ascendency in the
corridors of power in academia as well as the sphere of public policy. The
lessons of the Great Depression of the 1930s were set aside and neoliberal
economics became the framework for policy thinking. It prescribed
nonintervention in markets on the grounds that market regulation was
inefficient, except central bank control of the money supply. This led to
policies deregulating markets and fostering privatization, reducing the
public sector’s role and allowing the private sector free play.
Hussain (2006) has critiqued the neoliberal view that markets are
self-regulating and should be allowed to function unfettered in the context
of Pakistan. He argues that the view that “markets are self-organizing and
self-regulating” implies “a physiology of markets where the dynamics of
the market organism ... are independent of the specific history, institutional
framework and the process of cultural change of any particular country.”
Yet the process of self-regulation as the neoliberal view suggests is a messy
and chaotic business, and “would necessarily occur in the concrete
historical and cultural context of a particular country.”
How long the mess would last and what the magnitude of the
chaos would be cannot be predicted by ”market developers, but would be
discovered by the people of that country.” On the basis of earlier research,
Hussain (2006) suggests that Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 3
what are referred to in the literature as ‘market distortions’
are not marginal but may be central to the functioning of a
significant part of the market space in Pakistan. The
asymmetric nature of factor and product markets and the
consequent allocative and distributional inefficiency may
be organic to the nature of markets as they exist in the
specific historical and social context of Pakistan.
Two years later, the world economy was struck by the greatest
economic crisis since the 1930s. Under the influence of neoliberal
economics, the US Glass-Seagall Act 1933, which forbade retail banks from
engaging in risky investment activities such as selling securities, was
repealed in 1999 (Skidelsky, 2010, p. 7). Such market deregulation was a
key factor responsible for the world economic crisis in 2008. The neoliberal
thesis that markets are self-regulating proved to be spectacular folly with
tragic consequences for human societies across the capitalist world.
Neild’s (2009) seminal study provides a powerful critique of
economic orthodoxy, which he calls the general theory of market
economics. He argues: “the problem is that competitive endeavour can run
wild if it is not prudently constrained and policed by government. The
orthodox theory of market economies has failed to provide adequate
guidance as to why and how constraint should be applied” (p. 1).
Just as the Great Depression of the 1930s as indeed the current
world economic crisis have made clear, markets as they exist are subject to
periodic failure not because of “market distortions” but because of the
structural imperfections that are organic to their actual functioning. These
include individual choice with imperfect information, the absence of an
adequate self-correcting mechanism, and the unequal distribution of power
where large economic organizations are interlinked. They can make highly
risky individual decisions that can have a major impact on the economy as
a whole. Investment decisions by individuals and organizations are based
on the probability of individual rather than systemic risk, which can lead to
greater risk in investment choices than any one individual economic actor
is able to estimate. Spence (2009) points out that, in a situation where
individual risks are positively correlated and where the distribution of
individual risk is changing, estimating systemic risk becomes inherently
difficult.
In the case of Pakistan, the neoliberal idea is that incentives for
innovation and risk taking will necessarily lead to the emergence of 4 Akmal Hussain
dynamic entrepreneurs, who will then lead the economy to sustained high
GDP growth. As Hussain (2006) argues, this view ignores the possibility
that entrepreneurs in Pakistan respond not simply to profit incentives and
the presumed discipline of the market, but to a matrix of institutions that
embody both formal and informal rules. “The latter are contained in norms
and culture that change much more slowly than government policy. The
economic elite in the areas that now constitute Pakistan has historically
functioned within a patron–client model of governance since the late 18th
century” (Hussain, 2006, p. 3). As Ali (2003) suggests, underlying the
apparent discourse of modernity is the notion that neither the polity nor
the economy has made a fundamental break from the past.
3. Institutional Structure and Unsustainable Economic Growth
3.1. Governance Model and Rents
Central to the problem of unsustainable growth is a governance
model where the institutional structure systematically generates rents for
the ruling elites. North, Wallis, and Weingast define rents as unearned
income that accrues to an economic asset when the benefit from its use
exceeds its opportunity cost (2009, p. 19). In Pakistan, power has been
historically constituted through rents by establishing patron–client
relationships within a structure of dependency. In order to build political
support, the ruling elites appropriate and use state resources for arbitrary
transfer as rents to selected individuals and groups.
The rent-based model of governance originated under the British
Raj in the 19th century, when the exigencies of establishing order required a
convivial relationship with the new agrarian elite in the Punjab. This new
elite had emerged following the peasant revolts in the late 18th century
when the preceding Mughal elite was overthrown and replaced by the
leaders of the revolt from among the upper strata of the peasantry (see Ali,
1988, 2003).
In the process of establishing colonial power, the British
government consolidated the position of the new peasant lineages through
revenue settlements that formalized the proprietorship of the new
zamindars over land. Rent transfers in the form of resource gratification for
the new agrarian elite was unprecedented in Indian history, and was
accompanied by the British government’s development of the canal
irrigation system and the associated process of agriculture colonization in
the late 19th century. These areas were appropriated by the government as Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 5
Crown waste to be utilized or disposed of at administrative or political
discretion. Landholdings of between 100 and 500 acres were granted to
existing members of the landed elite who were loyal to the Raj. Some
particularly favored individuals received much larger holdings (Hussain,
2008b).
Post-independence, the governance model and underlying
institutional structure continue to systematically generate rents for the
coalition of elites that had emerged. These included the landed elite of the
pre-Partition period as well as the military, bureaucracy, and a statesupported
nascent entrepreneurial elite. Particular forms of rents have
characterized the policy and power framework of each government in the
post-independence period. For example, in the first decade after
independence, the principal form of rent was the grant of “evacuee”
property by the government to selected migrants from India.
During the Ayub Khan period (1958–68), various forms of rent
emerged through the regulatory economic policy framework. The modes
of rent transfers that were made to a small industrial and commercial elite
during this period included: direct and indirect subsidies, protectionist
import controls, cheap imported machinery and raw materials through an
overvalued exchange rate and subsidized credit to favored entrepreneurs
who were granted licenses to establish commercial and industrial
enterprises.
During the Z. A. Bhutto period (1973–77), the main forms of rent
consisted of lucrative appointments in the nationalized sector to favored
individuals, government contracts, and bank loans. Rents were also
transferred to loyalists through the new system of “lateral entry” where
individuals could be granted direct entry at various levels into the elite
Civil Service of Pakistan. Perhaps the largest source of rent transfers to a
broad range of upper, middle, and working classes was conducted through
the state-sponsored export of human resources to the Middle East
(Hussain, 2008b, p. 40).
During the Zia-ul-Haq period (1977–88), a new form of rent
generation emerged with the inflow of multibillion-dollar economic and
military aid to Pakistan when it was positioned to play a frontline role in
the US-sponsored Afghan jihad against Soviet troops in Afghanistan. The
Pakistan government acted as a conduit for funds and weapons to support
the war, during which a significant proportion of these funds and the sale 6 Akmal Hussain
of some of the weapons enriched individuals and groups favored by the
government.
Under the Benazir Bhutto and Nawaz Sharif governments, the
principal form of rent was the alleged siphoning of large funds from public
sector banks, insurance companies, and investment institutions such as the
National Investment Trust and the Investment Corporation of Pakistan.
During the Musharraf government, the government allegedly manipulated
stock markets to enrich insiders through the funds of banks and companies
in the nationalized sector (Hussain, 2008, p. 39).
3.2. Institutions and the Pattern of Economic Growth
Despite over six decades of economic growth post-independence,
mass poverty persists in Pakistan. This is because of an institutional
structure characterized by rent generation for the elites; a highly unequal
distribution of productive assets; and the exclusion of the majority of
people from access to productive resources, capital markets, and highwage
employment. Consequently, the process of saving and investment is
restricted to a small consumption-oriented elite coalition that has failed to
generate adequate savings and high rates of investment. At the same time,
the constrained competition characteristic of such an institutional structure
(North et al., 2009, p. 17) while generating rents for the elite creates
disincentives for diversifying exports toward high value-added growth.
Thus, two key constraints to sustaining high rates of GDP growth have
emerged: (i) a low savings rate and (ii) slow export growth.
Table 1 provides evidence on gross fixed capital formation (GFCF)
as a percentage of GDP in the private and public sectors under various
political regimes during 1960–2010. The table shows that private sector
gross investment as a percentage of GDP has remained low for the last five
decades under all political regimes, military or civilian. In six out of the
eight periods, private sector gross investment was below 10 percent and
reached about 14 percent during the Musharraf regime. Total gross
investment (private plus public) has also been low, varying between about
12 percent during Prime Minister Yousaf Raza Gillani’s regime to about 18
percent during the Musharraf regime.
Table 1: GFCF as a percentage of GDP and GDP growth rates, 1960–
2011
Average GFCF as a percentage of GDP Annual GDP growth Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 7
during Private Public Total rate (period average)
1960–73 8.21 7.26 15.47 6.26
1973–78 4.79 10.71 15.50 4.99
1978–88 7.10 9.66 16.76 6.6
1988–93 9.22 8.73 17.95 4.92
1993–98 9.32 7.36 16.68 3.14
1998–2008 11.23 3.72 14.95 6.25*
2008–11 10.85 1.34 12.19 2.62
* Refers to the period 2002–08.
Source: Pakistan economic survey (various issues).
At existing levels of income inequality, Pakistan requires a GDP
growth rate of about 8 percent to have a substantial poverty reduction
impact. To sustain a long-term GDP growth rate of 8 percent, investment as
a percentage of GDP needs to be about 32 percent, given the incremental
capital–output ratio (ICOR) of about 4. If Pakistan is to move onto a highgrowth
trajectory and reach the required investment target of 32 percent,
while increasing the growth elasticity of poverty reduction, then a change
in the institutional structure for broad-based investment is necessary. This
will require institutional changes through which the middle classes and the
poor can be enabled to engage in the process of saving, investment,
productivity increase, and innovation.
The New Institutional Economics literature shows that a defining
feature of developed countries is their ability to sustain per capita GDP
growth over long periods, while underdeveloped countries achieve brief
spurts of per capita income growth but are unable to sustain it over longer
periods (North et al., 2009, p. 6). The evidence shows that a fundamental
factor underlying the characteristic failure of underdeveloped countries to
sustain high GDP growth rates is their rent-based institutional structure,
which inhibits broad-based competition, investment, productivity increase,
and innovation.
The history of Pakistan’s economic growth performance shows a
structural inability to sustain growth. As Table 1 indicates, growth has
occurred in brief spurts followed by sharply declining GDP growth.
Relatively high GDP growth rates were achieved mainly during the
military regimes when large concessionary capital inflows from the West
were available to fuel growth. The average annual GDP growth during the
military regimes of Ayub Khan and Yahya Khan (1960–73) was 6.26 8 Akmal Hussain
percent, which declined to 4.99 percent in the subsequent period of Z. A.
Bhutto’s government (1973–78).
GDP growth accelerated again to 6.6 percent during the Zia-ul-Haq
period (1978–88), followed by a sharp decline in the subsequent democratic
interludes of Benazir Bhutto and Nawaz Sharif (1988–93 and 1993–98,
respectively). Another spurt occurred during the Musharraf period (1998–
2008) when GDP growth reached 6.25 percent, declining sharply to 2.62
percent under the subsequent government of Yousaf Raza Gillani (2008–
11). It is clear that each of these spurts was followed by a decline in growth.
At the end of each high-growth period, the structural constraints of a low
domestic savings rate and slow export growth were manifested in fiscal
and balance of payments pressures, which induced a subsequent
slowdown in GDP growth.
3.3. Low Savings Rate, Taxation, and Inequality
Given the rent-based governance model in Pakistan, the business
elite enjoys various forms of financial support from the government
(subsidies, cheap credit, import protection, tax exemptions). It is not
surprising, therefore, that entrepreneurs—many of whom are also
landowners—following the tradition of the landed elite, engage in
conspicuous consumption and tend to have a low propensity to save.
Historically, the domestic savings rate in Pakistan has been less
than the investment rate, thereby creating a persistent savings gap that has
induced growing national debt, particularly during high GDP growth
periods. For example, average annual domestic savings as a percentage of
GDP during 2001–2007 was 16.5 percent. By contrast, the investment rate
required to sustain the target growth rate of 8 percent with an ICOR of 4 is
32 percent (Pakistan, Ministry of Finance, 2007, p. 11, table 1.6). The
consequent debt-servicing problem has now become a constraint to growth
just as it was in the Ayub period in the 1960s and in the Benazir and
Nawaz periods in the 1990s. The low savings rate and consequent
dependence on foreign inflows is a major factor in the stop–go pattern of
GDP growth in Pakistan’s history.
The high debt-servicing requirements resulting from the rentseeking
elite’s tendency to consume rather than save, while also avoiding
direct taxes, has obliged successive governments to levy high and
increasing indirect tax rates. An earlier study on the increase in the
incidence of the tax burden shows that the increase in the tax burden as a Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 9
percentage of income was highest at 6.8 percent for the lowest income
group (less than PRs 700 per month) and lowest for the highest income
group (at –4.3 percent, over PRs 4,500 per month). The evidence shows
that, over time, the tax burden on the poor has increased and declined for
the rich (see Pakistan, Ministry of Finance, 1997, p. 6). Thus, the rent-based
governance model and its incentive systems have induced a pattern of elite
consumption and government tax policy that reinforces income inequality
in the growth process.
Given the highly unequal distribution of productive assets in
Pakistan, interpersonal inequality has risen in recent years. The Gini
coefficient for income, which was 0.27 in 2000/01 (World Bank, 2005, p.
281), has increased over the last decade; the average for the period 2000–11
is 0.327 (United Nations Development Programme, 2011, p. 137). Even this
level of inequality is understated because the top decile of the population
tends to understate their income and expenditure to avoid taxes. Shahid
Javed Burki has derived improved estimates of inequality in Pakistan on
the basis of World Bank data. He suggests that the top 10 percent of
the population holds 27 percent of the national income. The richest 18,000
people have an average income of USD 72,700 per capita, which is about 70
times the overall per capita income of USD 1,050 of the population as a
whole.
As is now well known, the higher the initial income inequality, the
lower the impact of GDP growth on poverty reduction will be. Pakistan’s
high and rising economic inequality has shaped the structure of the growth
process whereby mass poverty persists despite the relatively high trend
rate of GDP growth (5.5 percent).
3.4. Manufacturing, Export Structure, and Growth1
In 1947, Pakistan inherited not only various state institutions with
their underlying structures of power, but also the rent-seeking and riskaverse
behavioral proclivities of the economic elite.
Pakistan’s failure to adequately diversify exports—and hence the
slow export growth and consequent perennial pressures on the balance of
payments—is a structural constraint to sustaining high GDP growth. Even
after 60 years of industrial growth, the percentage of total investment
1 This section draws on Hussain (2008a). 10 Akmal Hussain
channeled into textiles and related goods has not declined (it was 41
percent in 1964/65 and 44 percent in 1990/91). In terms of output, 80
percent of Pakistan’s manufactured exports consist of textiles and clothing,
compared to 12 percent for developing countries and 6.5 percent for the
world as a whole (World Trade Organization, n.d.). The persistence of
Pakistan’s textile-based export structure is an important factor hampering
overall export growth. This is because the composition of demand in the
global market has changed: world trade in textiles is growing at a much
slower rate than nontraditional manufactured exports.
Pakistan’s textile industry, which has remained largely at the lower
end of the value-added range, emerged in the 1960s as a result of large
government subsidies. The institutional structure of policy created
disincentives to innovation, productivity, and export diversification. By the
1990s, the structure of state support to industry had been substantially
dismantled. However, even then, as late as 1990/91, as much as 7 percent
of GDP was transferred by the government to industrialists in the form of
subsidies (Kemal, 1999). The diversification of industry into higher valueadded
exports was constrained by government patronage on one hand and
the lack of risk-taking dynamism among most industrialists on the other.
For the manufacturing sector as a whole, the major elements in the
current institutional structure that constrain investment and growth are as
follows.
• The continued threat to citizens’ lives and property due to
persistently poor law and order. The total number of terrorist attacks
and other incidents of political violence in Pakistan increased from
254 in 2005 to 2,386 in 2008. The direct and indirect costs of the war on
terror during 2005–08 have been estimated at PRs 2,083 billion, with
the average annual cost being 4.34 percent of GDP (Institute of Public
Policy, 2009, p. 76, table 4.7).
• High electricity tariffs and frequent power outages. These incurred
an estimated overall cost to the economy of PRs 1228 billion in 2011-
12 which was 6.3 percent of GDP in that year. (Institute of Public
Policy, Sixth Annual Report 2013, p. 86).
• The adverse incentive/disincentive structure within the
institutional framework and an inadequate technological base.
These have constrained industry from responding flexibly as the
global pattern of demand changes toward higher value-added and
knowledge-intensive products. Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 11
• The adverse policy environment of the past. Tariff and export
incentives have been distorted against those entrepreneurs seeking to
improve quality and productivity for export growth (Pakistan,
Planning Commission, 2010).
• A weak enforcement mechanism within the government with
respect to trademark regulations and tariffs. This has led to the
widespread dumping of smuggled, poor-quality, and extremely lowpriced
imported goods from China, which are in many cases
counterfeits of branded Pakistani manufactured goods (Pakistan,
Planning Commission, 2010).
3.5. Institutional Factors in Slow and Unstable Crop Sector Growth2
In agriculture, the average annual growth rate of major crops
declined from 3.34 percent during the 1980s to 2.38 percent in the 1990s.
The frequency of negative growth years for some of the major crops has
also increased, accentuating the process of poverty creation. In a year of
negative growth (i.e., a bad harvest), small farmers operating at the margin
have to borrow to meet their consumption requirements, and thus fall into
debt. In the following season, in the absence of an investible surplus, they
are unable to reconstitute the production cycle and, hence, slip into
poverty. Thus, the instability of crop sector growth and increased
frequency of negative growth years has become a structural factor in
poverty creation.
Underlying this phenomenon are five major institutional
constraints. The first is reduced water availability at the farm gate due to
poor maintenance of the irrigation system and low irrigation efficiencies of
about 37 percent. While the availability of irrigation water has been
reduced, water requirements at the farm level have risen due to increased
salt deposits on the topsoil and the consequent need for leaching.3 The
resulting large water deficit means that farmers even in the irrigated areas
are dependent on rainfall. Given the vicissitudes of weather—particularly
due to global warming, which has caused wide variations in the timing,
location, and quantum of rainfall—rain does not always fall in the right
2 This section draws on Hussain (1999).
3 About 33 million tonnes of salts are annually brought into the Indus Basin irrigation system, out
of which 24 million tonnes are retained (see Pakistan, Finance Division, & Pakistan, Planning
Commission, 2001, p. 23). 12 Akmal Hussain
quantity at the right time for water-deficit farmers. Consequently, there is
greater instability in crop sector output than before (Hussain, 1999).
What makes the improved efficiency of irrigation even more
important is that the extensive margin of irrigated acreage has been
reached, so that future agricultural growth will have to rely on improving
the efficiency of water use and other inputs. Thus, the rehabilitation of
Pakistan's irrigation system to improve irrigation efficiency has become a
crucial policy challenge for sustainable agriculture growth.
It is well known that high-yielding seed varieties gradually lose
their potency through reuse, the changing microstructure of soils, and the
changing ecology of micro-organisms in the topsoil. The average age of
wheat seed in Pakistan is 11 years compared to 7 years in all developing
countries (Hussain, 1999). Therefore, breeding more vigorous seed varieties
adapted to local environmental conditions and diffusing these among
farmers through an effective research and extension program is necessary.4
The possibility of declining yields per acre related to global
warming indicates a new dimension of the imperative of improving
research capability in the crop sector. Given the sensitivity of wheat seed to
temperature increase, even a two-degree-centigrade increase in average
summer temperatures could mean an absolute yield decline of between 10
to 16 percent during the 21st century.5 With a 2.8 percent population
growth rate, a decline of 10 percent in yield per acre associated with global
warming could mean serious food deficits and high food inflation rates for
Pakistan, with greater adverse consequences for the poor. Indeed, the
United Nations’ Intergovernmental Panel for Climate Change (2007)
predicts a 30 percent decline in the yield per acre of food crops in South
Asia. It is, therefore, necessary to develop heat-resistant varieties of food
grains through an institutional framework for collaboration between
agriculture research centers across South Asia
4 Yet there is no organized seed industry in Pakistan to meet farmers’ needs for the supply of
vigorous varieties of seed, even for the major crops. Compared to India, there was a sharp decline
in total factor productivity growth in Pakistan after 1975, which can be attributed to the poorer
level of research and extension in Pakistan (see Rosegrant & Evenson, 1993).
5 If atmospheric carbon doubles, average summer temperatures in Pakistan are expected to increase
by 1.5 to 4.5 °C (a base average of 2.5 °C) over the next 70 years. This could lead to a decline in
wheat yields from 10 to 60 percent, depending on the type of wheat seed, planting time, and related
atmospheric/weather conditions (see Qureshi & Iglesias, 1992). Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 13
One of the most important constraints to sustainable growth in the
crop sector is soil degradation resulting from improper agricultural
practices such as: (i) lack of crop rotation and the resultant loss of humus in
the topsoil, (ii) the stripping of topsoil and resultant loss of fertility
associated with overgrazing, and (iii) water erosion along hillsides and
riverbanks due to the cutting down of trees and depletion of natural
vegetation. According to one estimate, over 11 million hectares have been
affected by water erosion and 5 million hectares by wind erosion (Mian &
Mirza, 1993).
4. Institutions, Markets, and Public Services
This section examines four features of the power structure that
makes markets asymmetric to function adversely against the poor.
4.1. Power, Tenancy, and Tied Labor
In areas where landowners control the local state apparatus as well
as the credit market, poor tenants are locked into a nexus of power and
debt bondage with their landowners. Consequently, the tenants are obliged
to work part time on landowners’ farms as laborers either at less than
market wage or no wage at all. The Pakistan National Human
Development Report (PNHDR)’s survey data shows that 51 percent of
tenants get locked into debt dependence on their landowner; out of these,
57 percent are obliged to work as laborers on the landowner’s farm without
wages, while 14 percent work for a wage below the market rate (Hussain,
Kemal, Ali, Hamid, & Mumtaz, 2003, p. 63, table 14). This structure of
power and dependence creates distortions in the labor and capital markets,
which systematically deprive the poor of their actual and potential income.
The consequent inefficiency in the allocation of labor and capital resources
constrains agricultural growth, increases inequality, and engenders
persistent poverty (see Table 2).
Table 2: Loan dependence on landowners and labor exploitation of the
poor peasantry
Status Extremely
poor
Poor Nonpoor Total
Loan from landowner (%) 50.8 29.4 11.7 34.4
Work for landowner against wages (%) 14.0 24.3 5.1 16.9
Daily wages (PRs) 28.0 43.6 60.0 40.0
Work for landowner without wages (%) 57.4 38.5 25.4 43.5 14 Akmal Hussain
Source: National Human Development Report 2003; Poor Communities Survey of
Pakistan 2001 (Pakistan Institute of Development Economics).
4.2. Power and the Double Squeeze on the Peasantry
In landowner-dominated areas, a landowner’s power affects the
disposal of the produce by poor farm households, which has direct
consequences for their food consumption. As Table 3 shows, under
asymmetric tenure arrangements, extremely poor farmers are obliged to
pay a larger proportion of their farm produce to the landowner as rent
compared to other categories of the peasantry. For example, the extremely
poor have to pay 28.21 percent of their production value to the landowner
compared to 13.39 percent by poor households and only 8.41 percent by
nonpoor households. Consequently, the extremely poor are forced to keep
only 39.59 percent of their crop output for household consumption,
compared to 48 percent by the poor and 54 percent by the nonpoor.
Table 3: Disposal of crop harvest by income class
Economic
status
Total
production
value
Paid
in
kind
to
labor
Paid
as
rent
Paid to
landowner
under
share
cropping
agreement
Given to
relatives
Crop
sold
Crop kept
for own
use/total
production
value*100
(Value)/total production value*100
Extremely
poor
13,864 1.45 1.10 28.21 0.09 29.57 39.59
Poor 22,538 2.76 1.40 13.39 1.06 33.27 48.12
Nonpoor 37,626 4.70 0.83 8.41 1.61 30.02 54.43
Source: National Human Development Report 2003; Poor Communities Survey of
Pakistan 2001 (Pakistan Institute of Development Economics).
The evidence suggests that poor tenant households face a food
deficit near the end of the year due to the relatively small crop share they
have been able to retain. As they run out of their household stock of food
grain, they are obliged to purchase grain in the market at the year’s end
when market prices are relatively high.6 Such households then need to
borrow for food consumption. The PNHDR evidence supports this
6 An analysis of the mechanisms of poverty generation in the rural areas (with special reference to
the Punjab) was first conducted on the basis of a 1978 field survey. See Hussain (1988, chap. 5, pp.
101–176). Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 15
argument, and shows that extremely poor households borrow to meet their
food consumption needs (Hussain et al., 2003, chap. 3, table 1).
Poor farm households are thus placed under a double squeeze. In
the first instance, they are obliged to give up a relatively large proportion
of their crop output as a crop share to the landowner. The second squeeze
is a result of seasonal variations in the market price of grain, which forces
extremely poor households to purchase a relatively large proportion of
their food consumption requirements from the market near the end of the
production cycle, when prices are high (Hussain, 2004, pp. 76–77).
4.3. Adverse Changes in Tenancy Arrangements and Poverty
As the evidence suggests, since the majority of the rural poor are
tenants, any deterioration in tenancy arrangements would be expected to
accentuate their poverty. The weakening relative power position of poor
tenants means that tenancy arrangements have changed adversely for
them. They now have to bear a higher proportion of input costs than their
landowners on tenant-operated farms. As Table 4 shows, tenants’
contribution to input costs (for each of the major crops)—such as tractor
rental (see Hussain et al., 2003, p. 64, table 16), hired labor, and seed and
fertilizer—increased during 1990/91 to 2000/01.
Table 4: Tenants’ contribution to inputs (percent)
Economic
status
1990/91 2000/01
Tractor Labor Seed Fertilizer Tractor Labor Seed Fertilizer
Extremely
poor
36.3 13.8 24.8 26.0 43.5 28.5 31.0 31.8
Poor 29.5 18.8 22.8 24.5 41.3 30.5 34.5 34.0
Nonpoor 39.8 25.8 28.8 27.3 44.5 32.8 38.8 34.5
Total 34.3 22.5 24.8 25.5 42.8 30.3 34.0 33.3
Source: National Human Development Report 2003; Poor Communities Survey of
Pakistan 2001 (Pakistan Institute of Development Economics). For crop-wise figures, see
Hussain et al. (2003, p. 64, table 16).
The above evidence suggests that the adverse changes in tenancy
arrangements with respect to tenants’ input contributions have become a
significant structural factor in generating poverty. While the financial
burden on poor tenants has thus increased, their lack of control over the
timing of water application, combined with adulterated inputs, keeps the
yield per acre low, thereby further squeezing their net incomes. 16 Akmal Hussain
4.4. Asymmetric Markets for Inputs and Outputs
Hussain et al. (2003) argue that local elite power structures in rural
areas distort markets in favor of the rich and against the poor. Poor
peasants face input and output markets in which they have to pay a higher
price for their inputs while receiving a lower price for their outputs than
large farmers. The study shows that the latter lose as much as one third of
their income due to asymmetric markets (pp. 65–68).
4.5. Poverty and Illness
Hussain et al. (2003) show that 65.1 percent of the extremely poor
and 55.6 percent of the poor in the PNHDR’s sample survey suffered from
ill health due to inadequate diets and lack of access to safe drinking water
and sanitation facilities. The data also shows that poor respondents
reporting sickness at the time of the interview had, on average, been
unwell for 95 days of the year (see table 5).7
The prevalence of disease among those who are slightly above the
poverty line is a major factor pushing them into poverty. Those who are
already poor are pushed deeper into poverty as a result of loss of income
due to absence from work and high medical costs incurred by illness. Thus,
unequal access to public health facilities and the relatively high prevalence
of disease among the poor becomes a structural factor that accentuates both
poverty and inequality (Hussain et al., 2003).
Table 5: Profile of the poor who are sick (household head only)
Economic
status
Sick at the
time of
survey (%)
Number of
days of
current
sickness
(mean)
Treatment
expenses
(PRs)
Patients
traveling over
6 km for
treatment (%)
Extremely poor 65.1 94.9 1,885 49.4
Poor 55.6 27.4 497 29.5
7 They also relied predominantly on private allopathic medical practitioners due to lack of access to
and the poor quality of most government hospitals. Private medical clinics, like government
hospitals, have grossly inadequate diagnostic facilities and often poorly trained staff. The result is
that when the poor fall ill, they suffer for a protracted period and are locked into a source of
medical treatment that, despite being expensive, is frequently ineffective (see Hussain et al., 2003). Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 17
Source: National Human Development Report 2003; Poor Communities Survey of
Pakistan 2001 (Pakistan Institute of Development Economics).
4.6. Education, Poverty, and Growth
The relatively low levels of literacy, high-school enrolment rates,
and poor quality of both school-level and higher education in Pakistan
compared to other South Asian countries indicates the low priority given to
education. This is understandable in a country where the allocation of
public resources and the institutional framework for translating them into
outcomes are determined by a ruling elite dominated by the military,
bureaucracy, and landowners.
This power structure affords greater priority to expenditures on the
military, bureaucracy, and transfer of public resources as rents to various
strata of the elite and its dependents. Building an institutional framework
for higher education based on high-quality research is also not a high
priority. Education requires resources and institutional mechanisms for
high-quality teaching, research, and the infrastructure facilities to pursue
these activities. At the same time, it is necessary to have an environment of
intellectual freedom to pose and pursue new questions and to engage in
critical thinking. This is inimical to a rent-based power structure that relies
on authoritarian rule, whether in military or civilian form.
Although the literacy rate has increased sharply from 46 percent in
1999 to 54 percent in 2006, the gender gap remains high (23 percentage
points) and has not changed significantly over the period.8 The gross
primary school enrolment rate at about 70 percent has remained
unchanged over the last two decades in spite of the multibillion-dollar
Social Action Program of the 1990s. At the same time, almost 25 percent of
the total population (over 40 million) consists of adult illiterates. Due to the
relatively low school enrolment rates, the number of adult illiterates is
expected to rise during the coming decade, thereby increasing poverty
even if greater employment opportunities become available. In Pakistan,
91.6 percent of the labor force is unskilled (Majid, 1997, pp. 34–35), with
low productivity and poor adaptability to technical change. This
constitutes a significant structural constraint both to growth and poverty
reduction.
8 Estimates based on Pakistan, Ministry of Finance (2007, pp. 161–174). 18 Akmal Hussain
The survey evidence in the PNHDR shows that one of the key
factors that can pull a poor household out of poverty is the presence of a
second earner. The data indicates that the magnitude of the second earner’s
income depends on his/her level of education (Hussain et al., 2003). The
poor coverage and quality of school education and vocational training in
Pakistan thus constitutes a significant structural constraint to growth as
well as poverty reduction. The extremely poor quality of higher education
in most Pakistani universities and control of some of them by obscurantist
and coercive religious groups is as much a constraint to equitable growth
as it is to building an enlightened, pluralistic, and democratic polity.
4.7. Poverty, Justice, and Citizens’ Security
The poor live in urban or rural localities that are inadequately
policed. In case of theft or violence against their person, the cost of seeking
redress through the judicial system is, in most cases, unaffordable; where
undertaken, the expenses in terms of time and money lock the poor into
permanent debt. This also engenders endemic poverty, reinforces
inequality, and thereby constrains economic growth (see Table 6).
Table 6: Frequency of disputes and resolution, and cost of resolution by
economic status (cases reporting disputes only)
Economic
status
Distribution of
reported disputes
(%)
Amount spent on
mediation (mean)
(PRs)
Percent of
reported disputes
resolved
Extremely poor 17.1 18,333 38.5
Poor 48.7 12,074 59.5
Nonpoor 34.2 18,264 80.8
Total/average 100.0 15,123 63.2
Source: National Human Development Report 2003; Poor Communities Survey of
Pakistan 2001 (Pakistan Institute of Development Economics).
5. Building Poverty Reduction into the Structure of the Growth
Process
The preceding section has identified some of the structural factors
underlying endemic poverty and unstable growth. This section presents a
set of institutional initiatives that can be undertaken to initiate the process
of pro-poor growth, helping to overcome the structural constraints to
sustained and equitable growth. These include: (i) providing land to the
landless as part of a new small farmer-based agriculture growth strategy, Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 19
(ii) mainstreaming the poor by establishing large corporations owned by
the poor but run by professionals, and (iii) overcoming the institutional
constraints to the rapid growth of small-scale enterprises (SSEs). These
three initiatives are only outlined in this section, since they have are
discussed at length in Hussain (in press). A fourth initiative, participatory
development, is elaborated in Section 6 of this chapter.
Pro-poor growth can be defined as a process that directs a
disproportionate share of the increase in national income toward the poor.
Going beyond this, restructuring the growth process in favor of the poor
involves empowering them to participate in the economic, social, and
political decisions that affect their material conditions.
Designing a policy for pro-poor growth involves addressing the
structural features of Pakistan’s growth process that constrain its capacity
at the macro-level for poverty reduction (see Sections 3 and 4). Therefore, at
the macro-level, a pro-poor growth policy should aim to achieve increased
employment elasticities and lower ICORs by increasing the weight in GDP
of microenterprises, and the output of small farms and small-scale
manufacturing enterprises. The strategy would also feature institutions
that could take to scale a localized process of capital accumulation through
participatory development.
5.1. Land for the Landless
One of the most important factors in endemic poverty in rural areas
(where the majority of Pakistan’s poor reside) is that millions of
households do not own any land or that their ownership of this productive
asset is less than the critical level required for subsistence. The data shows
that poor peasants who do own land have, on average, 2 acres, while larger
farmers are able to rent additional land. Poor farmers either rent out their
small owned holdings for a pittance or are obliged to sell their land
altogether (Hussain, 2008a). For example, according to the PNHDR’s
sample survey, as many as 76.5 percent of extremely poor farmers and 38.9
percent of poor farmers sold their land over the period 1990–2000 (Hussain
et al., 2003). The evidence shows that the poor have to sell their land to
meet urgent consumption needs related to health expenditure, crop
failures, and weddings. Thus, lack of access to this vital productive asset is
an important structural factor in endemic poverty.
Farms smaller than 25 acres constitute about 94 percent of the total
number of farms and about 60 percent of the total farm area. This sector 20 Akmal Hussain
has untapped potential for increasing the yield per acre on cropland and
increasing the output of milk and livestock products. As discussed
elsewhere, a new small–medium farmer-based agriculture growth strategy
could be initiated to transfer the existing 2.6 million acres of state-owned
land to landless peasants (see Hussain 2008a, in press). This could be
supported by the establishment of a small–medium farmer-owned
corporation through a public–private partnership that would provide them
with the following facilities: land development; access to high-quality
seeds, fertilizers, and marketing services; extension services to improve the
application efficiency of irrigation; and new technologies for high valueadded
crop farming such as tunnel farming.
5.2. Mainstreaming the Poor through Equity Stakes9
One institutional change that could bring the poor into the
mainstream market economy would involve establishing professionally
managed public limited companies in which the poor have a substantial
equity stake (for a more detailed discussion of the institutional framework
of such an initiative, see Hussain, in press). This concept was first
propounded by Professor Rehman Sobhan and successfully tried out in the
diversification process of the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh. It was also
tried out in India by Dr Verghese Kurien who set up Amul (originally a
cooperative), which is owned entirely by the poor and is now one of the
largest manufacturers of milk products in South Asia’s corporate sector.
In Pakistan’s case, there may be considerable potential for
developing livestock and milk production by the rural poor and supplying
these products to large private sector corporations for the manufacture and
export of milk and meat products. The private sector corporations that
would buy their inputs from the poor could also be owned substantially by
the poor. The equity stake to the poor could be achieved initially through
the provision of loans to be paid back from the corporations’ dividends.
Similar public limited companies owned by the poor and run by competent
professionals could also be established in key mainstream sectors of the
economy such as energy, telecommunications, and electronics.
9 This section draws on Hussain (in press). Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 21
5.3. Institutions for Stimulating Growth of SSEs
SSEs in small towns and peri-urban localities of Pakistan have
considerable growth potential because of their highly skilled technicians
and innovative entrepreneurs. However, their growth is constrained by the
following institutional factors: (i) lack of institutional linkages for
subcontracted work with the large-scale manufacturing sector; (ii) lack of
access to specialized fabrication facilities such as forging and heat
treatment, which are necessary for the dimensional control of high valueadded
metal products; (iii) lack of expertise in establishing quality control
procedures for the production of bulk orders; and (iv) lack of access to
credit facilities and working capital with which to purchase high-quality
raw materials.
These constraints could be overcome by facilitating the
establishment of common facilities centers in the private sector. These
could provide services such as linking SSEs with the large-scale
manufacturing sector through marketing services; specialized fabrication
facilities on a rental basis to SSEs; specialized training in production
management and quality control; and access to credit for the purchase of
high-quality raw materials and specialized equipment (see Hussain, 2009a,
pp. 26–30; in press).
6. Sustaining Growth Through Participatory Development
6.1. The Nature of Poverty and Human Potential
Like all human beings, the poor, too, have creative potential.
Denied the minimum food and basic necessities, such as health and
education; excluded from access to investible resources, training and highwage
employment; and living in atomized communities, the poor in
Pakistan are, however, unable to actualize their human potential.10 The
process of experiencing human potential as indeed of overcoming poverty
involves a new relation with the community and oneself. It is when
fragmented communities are reconstructed and organized to enable
individuals to gain equitable access to markets, skill training, and credit
that the poor can transform their condition. It is through creative thinking
10 Aristotle (1980, book 1, section 5) proposed that human functioning is the real object of value.
The implication of this formulation for public action today in the context of poverty is that
maximizing value in society requires enabling the maximum number of people to actualize their
human potential. 22 Akmal Hussain
and action in harmony with the community for a better life that the poor
experience their human potential.
The process of rediscovering community identity, acquiring new
skills, upgrading their knowledge, and being able to take initiatives to
improve their economic condition together with others, gives the poor new
power over the social forces that shape their lives. This consciousness
allows them to shift out of their self-perception of passive victims to active
subjects able to initiate individual and collective interventions to overcome
their poverty.
This consciousness of their potential to bring about change and the
institutional capacity to actualize it constitutes empowerment: it gives the
poor the ability to undertake a sustained increase in incomes by breaking
out of the nexus of elite power that has locked them into a structure of
dependence at the local level and systematically deprives them of a
significant proportion of their incomes (see Section 3).
6.2. Participatory Development: Individuals, Communities, and Markets
Participatory development involves a dialectical relationship
between the formation and progressive strengthening of group identity on
one hand and the improvement of the individual household’s material
conditions on the other.11 Community organizations (COs) change the
balance of power at the local level in favor of the poor by giving them
improved access to markets. As a CO emerges, it enables individual
members to acquire skill training, achieve productivity increase, and obtain
credit and access to product markets to systematically increase their
household incomes, savings, and investment. Thus, a localized process of
capital accumulation begins that is sustained by the leverage over markets
and public sector services that COs enable.
This interaction between the individual, CO, and markets helps to
strengthen group identity with each successful income generation project
at the individual level. Strengthening the CO becomes, in turn, the basis of
more complex and diversified projects. These can range from individual
11 The discussion on participatory development in this section is based on the author’s experience
of organizing poor rural communities in nine districts of the Punjab in 1998, when, as the first chief
executive officer of the Punjab Rural Support Program, he helped to initiate and establish the
program on the basis of the methodology of participatory development. For a field report, see
Hussain (2009b). Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 23
microenterprise projects to collective projects with spinoffs for individual
welfare such as localized irrigation projects and the development of
community schools and basic health services (Hussain, 1994).
6.3. Process of Participatory Development: Dialogues, Communities, and
Consciousness
The process of participatory development begins usually with an
external facilitator or development nongovernment organization (NGO)
that initiates a series of dialogues with a particular community. The
dialogues are meant to identify a set of feasible income generation projects
that can be undertaken by individual households, possible sources of local
resource generation, and the community’s preferences with respect to
collective projects for the provision of skill training, education, and health
facilities. At the same time, these dialogues aim to rekindle the awareness
that individual welfare can be more effectively pursued through the
formation of a CO.
The size of any one CO is usually between 25 to 30 members, each
from a different household, and the formal rules of this organization
stipulate a weekly meeting of all the members, with a written record of the
minutes. At these meetings, members identify projects, monitor
implementation, help resolve teething troubles, and commit to supporting
households that are facing problems of access to markets and public
services in the pursuit of their individual income generation projects.
External expertise is also brought to bear by the CO during these meetings,
to facilitate household-level microenterprise projects or community-level
social and physical infrastructure projects. Thus, the participation of
members of a community is not through “representatives” who act on their
behalf; rather, each member of the organization is actively involved in
project identification, formulation, implementation, and evaluation.
The Punjab Rural Support Program (PRSP), established in 1998, is
testament to the efficacy of participation through the institutional structure
of a CO. Following dialogues with a peri-urban community near
Gujranwala, the households agreed to form a CO with the proposed
institutional structure if some of them could acquire their own weaving
machines (khaddis) for producing cotton mats (durris). These households
were already producing durris on an outsourcing basis for an urban
entrepreneur who provided the machines and thread but purchased the
output at an extremely low price to maximize his intermediary profit. This
arrangement yielded only PRs 3,000 per month to the producers. 24 Akmal Hussain
Facilitated by the PRSP, the CO members provided the social
collateral to obtain microfinance to purchase the machines and thread. The
independent household production of durris more than doubled their
income when they sold their product in the market. The CO ensured 100
percent payback on the loans that individual members had been granted.
Similarly, in a village near Multan, the PRSP’s dialogues resulted in
the formation of a women’s CO for the production of bamboo sunshades.
The CO was linked up with trainers who helped members to learn the
craft. They were then facilitated through the CO in selling their product in
the nearby market at a lucrative price. In both cases above, the weekly CO
meetings helped to identify the project, assess its feasibility, facilitate
implementation, and encourage members to save from their increased
incomes as a basis for enlarging their project.
In each of the provinces of Pakistan, peasants may be poor, but they
have inherited a rich cultural and philosophical tradition that is reflected in
their forms of apprehending social life, their poetry, and folklore. Through
their forms of love and social action, these peasants express their dreams
and make their history.
The consciousness of the poor peasantry has been deeply
influenced by Sufi saints. This emerges in their folklore and images of
contemporary language use, for example in the Punjab. A central
experiential reference point is love (ishq), as a mode of self-actualization.
The peasants understand self-development as inseparable from nurturing
the ability to love: It is a process of transcending the ego through a
connection with the other. Says Shah Hussain, the 17th century Sufi poet:
You are the woof and you the warp
You are in every pore
Says Shah Hussain Faqir
Naught am I, all is you.
Accordingly, the more developed a person’s consciousness, the
more he or she locates himself in the collective being of the community,
which Shah Hussain has expressed as follows:
The Faqirs have their being Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 25
in the coming together of the community
For their consciousness is in full bloom.
In the peasantry, the consciousness of the Sufi tradition is woven
into language use, and is manifest in the cadences of their speech as much
as their silences.
Najam Hussain Syed, the great contemporary Sufi poet, refers to
this subliminal consciousness of the peasantry as:
Somewhere on the slopes of silence
Beat the drums of the unsaid
and again as:
Far on the banks of memory falls
Your shadow, Ranjha.
In the process of participatory development through dialogue and
action, there are moments when this counter-consciousness of love and
relatedness of integrity and creative action, comes into play as a material
force in the process of social and economic change. The challenge in the
dialogues undertaken by the PRSP was to bring about this gestalt switch in
consciousness, through word, gesture, and work procedures.
6.4. Institutional Challenges in Taking Development NGOs to Scale
If participatory development is to make a significant contribution to
achieving inclusive growth in Pakistan, then COs need to be replicated at
the necessary speed and scale and at a feasible resource cost to be able to
have a national impact in the foreseeable future. Over the last few decades,
development NGOs in Pakistan have used various versions of community
participation, ranging in size from community-based organizations at the
village or mohallah level to the union council level, such as the Pakistan
Institute for Environment-Development Action Research (PIEDAR). Some
NGOs have scaled up to the district or multidistrict level (the Kashf
Foundation and Akhuwat). Others include large top-down governmentinitiated
NGOs at the provincial level—such as the rural support programs
in Punjab, Sindh, and Balochistan—and even the national level (the
National Rural Support Program). Some development NGOs have grown 26 Akmal Hussain
rapidly, others slowly; some unleash communities’ creative energies by
enabling them to be autonomous, while others are more bureaucratic.
Similarly, some development NGOs are cost-effective while others,
particularly government-created top-down ones, have prohibitively high
overheads.
In the case of some large top-down government-created NGOs,
questions with regard to key issues of feasibility persist. High overheads
create a continuing dependence on government and donor funds. The
inaccurate targeting of the poor with respect to credit and organizational
support poses a problem. Moreover, the pace at which poor populations
are covered is so slow and the cost of social mobilization so high, that the
prospect of covering a substantial proportion of the poor can become
impossible within a realistic timeframe and given the government’s
resources.
The central challenges in achieving scale in participatory
development are as follows. First, it is important to retain the autonomy of
each CO and its institutional mechanisms for nurturing community
consciousness and ensuring participation in project identification,
implementation, and monitoring. Second, rapid multiplication should
occur without falling prey to the formation of a centralized top-down
bureaucracy that tends to stifle the CO’s autonomy while being expensive.
Third, COs need to become financially independent of donors and the
government by keeping their overheads to a minimum and achieving
economies of scale through reduced administrative (social mobilization)
costs as the organization grows.
7. Conclusion
This chapter has examined the roots of Pakistan’s problem of
achieving sustained growth in terms of the economy’s institutional
structure and the country’s model of governance. The constraints to
sustained growth that take the form of a low domestic savings rate and
incapacity for adequate foreign exchange earnings are located in the
institutional structure. A growth process that is narrowly based on a group
of elites—generating rents for them by excluding the majority of people—
creates inequality, persistent mass poverty, and disincentives for saving,
efficiency, innovation, and international competitiveness.
The patron–client model of governance originated when, in the
process of establishing the British Raj in the 19th century, the new agrarian Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 27
elite that had emerged following the peasant revolts against Mughal rule in
the 18th century, was consolidated. This was done through revenue
settlements that formalized the proprietorship of the new zamindars and
rent transfers granting land to loyal zamindars during the development of
the canal irrigation system. The chapter has also discussed the various
forms of rent generated by successive governments in Pakistan postindependence
to show how the patron–client model of governance
inherited from the Raj, persisted.
Additionally, the chapter has examined the institutional factors
underlying slow growth in manufactured exports and unstable growth in
agriculture. It has analyzed the structures of power, tenancy, and tied labor
that systematically deprive the poor peasantry of a large proportion of their
income. The evidence shows how illness, lack of education, and lack of
access to justice play an important role in perpetuating poverty, inequality,
and slow growth.
If growth is to be sustained and poverty reduced rapidly, then the
process of investment and productivity needs to be broad-based to include
the poor and the middle classes in both the agriculture and manufacturing
sectors. This can be achieved through a new small farmer agriculture
growth strategy to provide land to the landless together with ancillary
services for land development, high-quality seed, improved irrigation
efficiency, and access to new farming practices and technologies. At the
same time, the growth of small and medium enterprises in the
manufacturing sector can be accelerated by establishing common facilities
centers in the main regional growth nodes.
Finally, the chapter has analyzed the nature of poverty and the
possibility of overcoming it in terms of institutions that could actualize the
human potential of the poor through participatory development. In this
context, the chapter has discussed the main features of participatory
development and the challenges of taking it to scale to show how the
development of community consciousness can play a vital role in
transforming the material conditions of the poor.
References
Ali, I. (1988). The Punjab under imperialism, 1885–1947. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press. 28 Akmal Hussain
Ali, I. (2003). Government patronage and rent-seeking elites: A longer historical
perspective (Background paper for the Pakistan national human
development report). Islamabad, Pakistan: United Nations
Development Programme.
Aristotle. (1980). The Nicomachean ethics (Book 1) (D. Ross, Trans.). Oxford,
UK: Oxford University Press.
Hussain, A. (1988). Strategic issues in Pakistan’s economic policy. Lahore,
Pakistan: Progressive Publishers.
Hussain, A. (1994). Poverty alleviation in Pakistan. Lahore, Pakistan:
Vanguard Books.
Hussain, A. (1998). Punjab rural support programme: The first four months
(Report submitted to the Board of Directors of the Punjab Rural
Support Programme). Lahore, Pakistan.
Hussain, A. (1999). Employment generation, poverty alleviation and growth in
Pakistan’s rural sector: Policies for institutional change (Mimeo).
Geneva, Switzerland: International Labour Office/Centre for
Economic Policy Research.
Hussain, A. (2004). Institutions, economic structure and poverty in
Pakistan. South Asia Economic Journal, 5(1), 69–102.
Hussain, A. (2006). Comments [on N. Haque, Pakistan’s growth strategy].
Pakistan Development Review, 45(1), 35–39.
Hussain, A. (2008a). Institutional imperatives of poverty reduction (Research
Paper Series). Lahore, Pakistan: Institute of Public Policy.
Hussain, A. (2008b). Power dynamics, institutional instability and economic
growth: The case of Pakistan. Islamabad, Pakistan: Asia Foundation.
Hussain, A. (2009a). Institutional framework for inclusive growth (Paper
submitted to the Panel of Economists for the Medium-Term Plan).
Islamabad, Pakistan: Planning Commission.
Hussain, A. (2009b). Participatory development praxis in Pakistan’s
Punjab: A case study. In P. Wignaraja, S. Sirivardana, & A.
Hussain (Eds.), Economic democracy through pro-poor growth. New
Delhi, India: SAGE Publications. Institutions, Economic Growth, and Participatory Development 29
Hussain, A. (in press). Strengthening democracy through inclusive
growth. In A. Hussain & M. Dubey (Eds.), Democracy, sustainable
development and peace: New perspectives on South Asia. New Delhi,
India: Oxford University Press.
Hussain, A., Kemal, A. R., Ali, I., Hamid, A. I., & Mumtaz, K. (2003).
Pakistan national human development report 2003: Poverty, growth and
governance. Karachi, Pakistan: Oxford University Press/United
Nations Development Programme.
Institute of Public Policy. (2009). State of the economy: Emerging from the
crisis. Lahore, Pakistan: Author.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. (2007). Climate change 2007:
Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. New York, NY: Cambridge
University Press.
Kemal, A. R. (1999). Patterns of growth of Pakistan’s industrial sector. In
S. R. Khan (Ed.), Fifty years of Pakistan’s economy. Karachi, Pakistan:
Oxford University Press.
Majid, N. (1997). Pakistan: An employment strategy. Geneva, Switzerland:
International Labour Office, South Asia Multidisciplinary
Advisory Team.
Mian, A., & Mirza, Y. (1993). Pakistan soil resources (National Conservation
Strategy, Sector Paper No. 4). Islamabad, Pakistan: Environment
and Urban Affairs Division/IUCN.
Neild, R. (2012). Economics in disgrace: The need for a reformation (Mimeo).
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social
orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history.
New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Pakistan, Finance Division, & Pakistan, Planning Commission. (2001).
Interim poverty reduction strategy paper. Islamabad, Pakistan:
Author.
Pakistan, Ministry of Finance. (1997). Overcoming poverty: Report of the task
force on poverty alleviation. Islamabad, Pakistan: Author. 30 Akmal Hussain
Pakistan, Ministry of Finance. (2007). Pakistan economic survey 2006–07.
Islamabad: Author.
Pakistan, Planning Commission. (2010). Medium-term development
imperatives and strategy for Pakistan. Islamabad: Author.
Qureshi, A., & Iglesias, A. (1992). Implications of global climate change for
Pakistan agriculture: Impacts on simulated wheat production.
Washington, DC: Climate Institute.
Rosegrant, M. W., & Evenson, R. (1993, January). Agricultural productivity
growth in Pakistan and India: A comparative analysis. Paper presented
at the 9th Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economists, Islamabad.
Skidelsky, R. (2010). Keynes: The return of the master. London, UK: Penguin
Books.
Spence, M. (2009). Agenda for the next few months. In B. Eichengreen &
R. Baldwin (Eds.), What G20 leaders must do to stabilize our economy
and fix the financial system. London, UK: Centre for Economic
Policy Research.
United Nations Development Programme. (2011). Human development
report 2011 – Sustainability and equity: A better future for all. New
York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.
World Bank. (2005). World development report 2006: Equity and development.
New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
World Trade Organization. (n.d.). International trade statistics. Retrieved
from
http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/stat_appendix_e.ht
m
No comments:
Post a Comment