1
CHAPTER 8
Strengthening Democracy through
Inclusive Growth
By
Akmal Hussain
Distinguished Professor of Economics,
Forman Christian College University,
Lahore
© January 2014 by Akmal Hussain. All rights reserved. Quotations from the text, not to exceed one
paragraph, may be made without explicit permission, provided that full credit, including © notice, is given
to the source.
Chapter published in, Akmal Hussain and Muchkund Dubey (ed.), Democracy,
Sustainable Development and Peace: New Perspectives on South Asia,
Oxford University Press, New Delhi, 2014 2
CHAPTER 8
Strengthening Democracy through
Inclusive Growth1
By
Akmal Hussain
INTRODUCTION
Militant extremism threatens Pakistan’s democracy as much as the integrity of the state.
It is clear that an important dimension of sustaining democracy and securing the state is
to provide a stake in citizenship to the large proportion of the population that is suffering
from growing poverty, unemployment and the deprivation of basic services. This is
necessary to prevent fresh breeding grounds for recruitment to the militant cause. In this
paper we will first identify some of the structural constraints to sustained economic
growth and rapid poverty reduction. We will then present an alternative paradigm of
achieving sustained growth through equity and specify the elements of a strategy for
achieving this aim.
THE STRUCTURAL CONSTRAINTS TO SUSTAINING GDP GROWTH AND
THE PROBLEM OF PERSISTENT POVERTY AND INEQUALITY
Economic growth in the past 60 years has failed to make a substantial dent into the
poverty problem. This is because of an institutional structure within which high economic
growth has been neither sustainable nor equitable. The pattern of high growth spurts,
followed by periods of slow growth is indicated in Table 1. The high growth periods have
broadly been associated with military regimes when large aid flows were available, while
the slow growth periods were associated with elected civilian governments who in most
cases could not attract sufficient foreign aid. The Table shows for example, that after an
1 This paper is based on an earlier version titled: Institutional Framework for Inclusive Growth
which was contributed to the research paper series of Beaconhouse National University and
circulated as a discussion paper in the Panel of Economists, 2009. This paper also draws upon
some of the author’s contribution to the Report of the Working Group on Poverty Reduction
Strategy and Human Resource Development, Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan,
Islamabad, 2010. 3
average annual GDP growth of 6.26 percent during the period of military regimes of
General Ayub and General Yahya (1960 to 1973), there was a sharp slowdown in the
subsequent period of democratic governance (1973 to 1978). Again during the General
Zia regime (1978 to 1988), the growth rate increased to 6.6 percent annually but declined
again in the following decade when democratic governments functioned (1988 to 1998).
In the subsequent period (1998 to 2007) GDP growth accelerated once again to 5.28
percent annually during the regime of General Musharraf, but declined sharply to 2.4
percent in the period 2008-11, when a civilian government was in power. As Table 1
shows the problems of balance of payments and fiscal deficits persisted over the last five
decades. Table 1 also shows that the problems of balance of payments and fiscal deficits
persisted over the last five decades.
Economic growth has not been sustainable because of a set of structural constraints2
, the
most important of which are: (i) A narrow base for savings which makes the savings rate
(less than 12 percent of GDP), half that of the investment rate (24 percent of GDP)
required to sustain a GDP growth rate of 6 percent3
. (ii) A narrow base for exports which
excludes potential small scale high value added export based industries and instead
concentrates on a small number of large scale textile units at the low value added end of
the textile range. Therefore export growth is insufficient to finance the foreign exchange
requirements of a high GDP growth trajectory. (As Column 2 in Table 1 shows, the
external trade deficit as a percentage of GDP remained quite high during most of
Pakistan’s economic history).
2
For a detailed discussion of the structural constraints to sustained growth, see: Akmal Hussain,
Pakistan: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, South Asia Centre for Policy Studies, MSS, 30
September 2008, pages 22 to 26. (Publication forthcoming).
3 The Incremental Capital Output Ratio (ICOR) for Pakistan’s Economy is, 4. 4
TABLE 1
PERIOD AVERAGES OF THE PERCENTAGE SHARE OF SELECTED
MACRO-ECONOMIC INDICATORS IN THE GDP OF PAKISTAN
Average During
Real GDP
Growth %
(Average
Annual)
Trade
Balance as
% of GDP
Debt
Servicing as
% of GDP
1960-1973 6.26 -5.11 1.28
1973-1978 4.99 -7.27 2.04
1978-1988 6.6 -8.66 2.44
1988-1993 4.92 -5 3.02
1993-1998 3.14 -3.99 3.48
1998-2007 5.28 2.93 5.3**
2008-2010 2.43 -10.44 6.1
Sources: Economic Survey of Pakistan and Federal Bureau of Statistics
** Estimate drawn from 2002-03 to 2006-2007
The evidence shows that while Pakistan’s elite based growth process has a stop go
pattern, at the same time the narrow base of savings and investments, and an extremely
unequal distribution of productive assets in both manufacturing and agriculture, has
resulted in growing income inequality during the high growth periods. Consequently the
capacity of growth for poverty reduction is severely constrained. Table 2 shows that after
over 60 years of GDP growth in the post independence period, the incidence of poverty
was over 40 percent, with the food insecure population being as high as 48.6 percent. The
inter-personal inequality is also significant, with Gini-coefficient which is a measure of
inter-personal inequality, being 32.7 percent. This figure is relatively low compared to
other South Asian countries, because of the tendency of the richest sections of the
population to understate their consumption expenditure to avoid income tax. Dr. Shahid
Javed Burki has derived more realistic estimates of inequality in Pakistan on the basis of
World Bank data. He suggests that the top 10 percent of the population claims 27 percent 5
of the national income4
. The poorest 10 percent of the population gets only 4 percent of
the national income, making the ratio between the top and bottom deciles of the
population as high as 6.7. Burki estimates that the richest 18,000 have an average income
of USD 72,700 per capita compared to the overall per capita income of USD 1,050 for
the population as a whole.
4
Shahid Javed Burki, How Rich are the Pakistani Rich?, The Express Tribune, May 16, 2011. 6
TABLE 2
INFLATION, POVERTY AND INEQUALITY, 2010
Inflation (CPI Index) 14.1
Food Inflation (%) 18.4
Food insecure population* 48.6
Incidence of Poverty (estimates) (%) 40.71**
Ratios of top decile of income to bottom decile of income 2.36
Gini-coefficient in mid 2000s 32.7***
Sources: Fourth Annual Report 2011, State of the Economy Devolution of Pakistan, Institute of Public
Policy, Beaconhouse National University, Lahore estimated from Pakistan Economic
Survey SBP, Annual Report & IMF.
* World Food Programme Publication on "Food Insecurity in Pakistan, 2009"
** First Annual Report 2008, State of the Economy, Institute of Public Policy, Beaconhouse
National University.
*** UNDP, Human Development Report 2011.
AN ALTERNATIVE POLICY PARADIGM: INCLUSIVE GROWTH
If growth is to be sustained and poverty is to be overcome quickly, a shift in the paradigm
for understanding both the determinants of growth as well as the nature of poverty is
required. The literature of the New Institutional Economics shows that the most
important determinant of sustained growth is the institutional structure within which it
occurs5
. If Pakistan is to embark on a path of sustained growth it would be necessary to
establish an institutional structure for inclusive growth. Such a growth process would
5
(i) Douglass C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, England, 2004.
(ii) Douglass C. North, Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton University
Press, 2005.7
provide the economic basis for sustaining democracy6
. The institutional structure of
inclusive growth would enable all of the citizens of Pakistan rather than only a small elite
to participate as subjects of economic growth as well as the recipients of its fruits.
In addressing the structural basis of poverty, it can be proposed that neither handouts to
the poor nor the trickle down effects of the conventional unequal growth process can
resolve the poverty problem. This is because the poor are locked into a nexus of power
within an institutional structure that gives them insufficient access to productive assets
and to health, skill development and education through which they could develop their
human potential7
. They also lack access over justice and over governance decisions that
affect their immediate social, economic and environmental conditions.
The Elements of Inclusive Growth
A new approach to inclusive growth could be adopted by establishing an institutional
framework for the provision of productive assets to the poor as well as the capacity to
utilize these assets efficiently8
. In this way the poor by engaging in the process of
investment, innovation and productivity increase could become the active subjects of
economic growth rather than being merely recipients of a “trickle down” effect: Thus a
sustained high growth could be achieved through equity9
. Inclusive growth so defined
can become both the means and the end of GDP growth.
6
For a discussion on Economic Democracy and case studies of action, See: Ponna Wignaraja, Susil
Sirivardana, Akmal Hussain (eds), Economic Democracy through Pro Poor Growth, SAGE
Publications, Delhi, 2009.
7 Akmal Hussain, Pakistan: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, South Asia Center for Policy
Studies, MSS, 30 September 2008, Forthcoming.
8 This idea was formulated in my paper titled: Pakistan: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth,
(2008), contributed to the SACEPS South Asia Poverty Study, and used as an input in the book,
Rehman Sobhan, Challenging the Injustice of Poverty, Agendas for Inclusive Development in
South Asia, SAGE Press, Delhi, 2010.
9
I am grateful to Professor A.K. Sen for pointing out to me, that while my argument that higher
growth could be achieved through equity is technically valid, yet it is important to understand that
equity is an end in itself. This comment was made by Professor A.K. Sen during a SACEPS/CPD
seminar (Equitising Development) in Delhi, 17-18 December 2008. 8
The institutional framework of such an inclusive growth could have four broad
dimensions:
(1) A process of localized capital accumulation through Participatory Development.
(2) A small and medium farmer strategy for accelerated agriculture growth through
the provision of land ownership rights to the landless and institutional
arrangements for yield increases.
(3) Accelerated growth of small and medium scale industrial enterprises through an
institutional framework for increasing the production and export of high value
added products in the light engineering and automotive sectors.
(4) An institutional framework for providing productive assets to the poor through
equity stakes in large corporations owned by the poor and managed by
professionals.
In this paper we will discuss each of these elements of inclusive growth in turn.
I. THE INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURE OF ENDEMIC POVERTY
10
I.1 The Poverty Process
The poor in Pakistan cannot be simply seen as individuals with certain adverse ‘resource
endowments’, making choices in free markets. Poverty occurs when the individual in a
fragmented community is locked into a nexus of power which deprives the poor of their
actual and potential income. The poor face markets, state institutions and local power
structures, which discriminate against access of the poor over productive assets, financial
resources, public services and governance decisions which affect their immediate
existence.
10 This section is based on Akmal Hussain: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, Pakistan Country
Study for the SACEPS Poverty Project, 30th September 2008. 9
I.2 Poverty, Power and Asymmetric Markets
Various forms of dependencies of the peasant on the local power structures and the
distortions in the input and output markets functioning against the poor, constitute the
elements of the process of poverty generation amongst the peasantry.
A substantial proportion of the potential as well as actual income of the poor peasantry is
lost to the increasingly adverse tenancy arrangements and the obligation to sell labour at
less than market wage rates or without any wages at all, to the landlords. This is because
of the social and economic leverage that the landlords exercise over the poor peasants.
For example, the NHDR data shows that 50.8 percent of the extremely poor peasants
have taken a loan from the landlord and of these peasants 57.4 percent worked for the
landlord without wages and 14 percent worked for the landlord at a daily wage rate of
only Rs.28, compared to the typical market daily wage rate of about Rs.15011
.
At the same time there is unequal access over both the input and the output markets. For
example, the NHDR data shows that the poor peasants have to pay a higher price on their
inputs and get a lower price on their outputs compared to the large farmers. As a
consequence the poor are losing 20.5 percent of their income in the major crops alone due
to asymmetric markets.
In the small farm households the most significant constraint to increasing income is lack
of ownership rights and the income losses associated with land use within the structure of
dependence. The evidence shows that the contribution of tenants to input costs in the case
of tractor rental, labour, seeds and fertilizers has increased during the period 1990-91 to
2000-01. For example, in the case of wheat the contribution of tenants in the provision of
tractors increased from 63 percent to 74 percent, labour from 47 percent to 60 percent,
seeds from 51 percent to 67 percent and fertilizers from 47 percent to 57 percent over the
period, 1990-91 to 2000-0112
. The poor owner farmers and owner cum tenant farmers in
the small size category instead of buying additional land have been forced to sell their
11 Ibid. Chapter 3, Table 14, Page 63.
12 See, Akmal Hussain, Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, op.cit., page-9, table 6. 10
land over the period 1991-2000-01. As many as 76.5 percent of the extremely poor
farmers and 38.9 percent of the poor farmers sold their land for urgent consumption
needs, marriage expenditures and health expenditures13
. As a consequence the productive
assets of the poor peasants have been further depleted, thereby adversely impacting their
future streams of income and reducing the probability of getting out of poverty.
Amongst the non rural farm households the principal constraint to poverty alleviation is
the limited possibility of remunerative jobs and the low ability to initiate self employment
projects. In the urban areas the employment status, lack of enforcement of minimum
wage legislation amongst workers in the informal sector, and the low level of
productivity of micro enterprises, constrain income levels and give rise to poverty14
.
II. INCLUSIVE GROWTH THROUGH PARTICIPATORY
DEVELOPMENT15
Establishing the institutional basis for enabling the poor to increase their incomes,
savings and investment, would not only constitute a direct attack on poverty but would
also contribute to a faster and more equitable economic growth process. In this section
we will begin by specifying the Participatory Development paradigm which has been
formulated and put into practice successfully in a number of South Asian countries
(including Pakistan) by a group of action researchers from South Asia led by Dr. Ponna
Wignaraja16. We examine the issue of empowerment of the poor. In this context we will
13 Ibid. page-9.
14 For evidence and detailed analysis of this phenomenon, see, Akmal Hussain, with inputs from
A.R. Kemal, Agha Imran Hamid, Imran Ali and Khawar Mumtaz: Pakistan UNDP-National
Human Development Report 2003, Oxford University Press, Karachi, 2003.
15 This section is drawn from Akmal Hussain, Pakistan: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth,
South Asia Center for Policy Studies, 30th September 2008. pages 119 to 125.
16 See, for example:
(i) Ponna Wignaraja, Akmal Hussain, Harsh Sethi and Ganeshan Wignaraja: Participatory
Development, Learning from South Asia, United Nations Press, Tokyo and Oxford
University Press, Karachi, 1991. 11
explore the institutional imperatives of making the newly emerging local government
structures more effective in achieving empowerment of the poor, particularly poor
women.
II.1 The Methodology of Participatory Development17
Participatory Development in its broadest sense is a process which involves the
participation of the poor at the village/mohalla levels to build their human, natural and
economic resource base for breaking out of the poverty nexus18. It specifically aims at
achieving a localized capital accumulation process based on the progressive development
of group identity, skill development, and local resource generation19
.
II.1.1 The Dynamics Of Participatory Development
The process of Participatory Development proceeds through a dynamic interaction
between the achievement of specific objectives for improving the resource position of the
local community and the sense of community identity. Collective actions for specific
objectives such as a small irrigation project, fertilizer manufacture through organic waste,
clean drinking water provision, or production activities such as fruit processing, can be an
entry point for a localized capital accumulation process, leading to group savings
(ii) Ponna Wignaraja and Susil Sirivardana, Pro-Poor Growth and Governance in South
Asia: Decentralization and Participatory Development, SAGE Publications, New Delhi
and London 2004.
(iii) Ponna Wignaraja, Susil Sirivardana, Akmal Hussain (eds), Economic Democracy
through Pro Poor Growth, SAGE Publications, Delhi, 2009.
(iv) Akmal Hussain, Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, Vanguard Books, 1994.
(v) Akmal Hussain, Punjab Rural Support Programme (PRSP), The First Four Months,
Report to the Board of Directors of PRSP, 1998.
17 Akmal Hussain, Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, Vanguard Books, 1994, page-26 to 28.
18 For a case study of a Participatory Development initiative in 9 districts of the Punjab based on
field experience, see: Akmal Hussain, The Punjab Rural Support Programme, The First Four
Months, Report of the Honorary CEO to the Board of Directors (1998). Also see: Akmal Hussain,
Participatory Development Praxis in Pakistan’s Punjab: A Case Study, chapter in, Ponna
Wignaraja, Susil Sirivardana, Akmal Hussain (eds), Economic Democracy through Pro Poor
Growth, SAGE Publications, Delhi, 2009.
19 Akmal Hussain, Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, op.cit.12
schemes, reinvestment and asset creation. The dynamics of Participatory Development
are based on the possibility that with the achievement of such specific objectives for an
improved resource position, the community would acquire greater self confidence and
strengthen its group identity20
.
II.2 Empowerment and Autonomous Organizations of the Poor
(i) The Meaning of Empowerment: Since the term empowerment has been loosely
used in much of the literature on development it may be helpful to specify its meaning in
the context of this paper. Empowerment means enabling the poor to build their human
capabilities and economic resource base for breaking out of the poverty nexus. It is a
process of reconstructing group identity, of raising consciousness, of acquiring new skills
and of achieving better access over markets and institutions for a sustainable increase in
incomes. Such a process progressively imparts to the poor a new power over the
economic and social forces that fashion their daily lives. It is through this power that the
poor shift out of the perception of being passive victims of the process that perpetuates
their poverty. Thus they become active subjects in initiating interventions that
progressively improve their economic and social condition to overcome poverty21
.
(ii) Empowering the Poor: The proposed economic strategy requires a national
campaign to empower the poor at the level of village/mohallah, Union Council, Tehsil
20 The theory and practice of Participatory Development was developed by a group of South Asian
scholars including Dr. Ponna Wignaraja (Sri Lanka), Dr. Akmal Hussain (Pakistan), Mr. Susil
Sirivardana, Mr. Harsh Sethi (India), Dr. Maqsood Ali (Bangladesh). Their published work
articulating the Methodology of Participatory Development and documenting their praxis includes
the following:
(i) Ponna Wignaraja, Akmal Hussain, Harsh Sethi and Ganeshan Wignaraja: Participatory
Development, Learning from South Asia, United Nations Press, Tokyo and Oxford
University Press, Karachi, 1991.
(ii) Akmal Hussain, Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, Vanguard Books, 1994.
(iii) Ponna Wignaraja, Susil Sirivardana, Akmal Hussain (eds), Economic Democracy through
Pro Poor Growth, SAGE Publications, Delhi, 2009.
21 For a case study based on implementing the Participatory Development approach in nine districts
of the Punjab province, see, Akmal Hussain, Honourary Chief Executive Officer, Punjab Rural
Support Programme (PRSP), The First Four Months Report to the Board of Directors, PRSP,
1998. 13
and District. The idea is to facilitate the growth of autonomous community organizations
of the poor at the village/mohallah level to be able to break out of the poverty. Through
these COs the poor can identify income generating projects, initially at the household
level, acquire skill training from a variety of sources such as government line
departments, autonomous institutions, private sector firms, NGOs. and donors; and access
credit for micro enterprise projects through apex organizations such as the PPAF,
Khushali Bank, Small Business Finance Corporation (SBFC), and commercial banks.
Special organizational arrangements would need to be made in these apex institutions to
take credit to poor women and women’s COs, since poor women have even lesser access
over institutional credit compared to poor men.
It is important that such village level community based organizations (CBOs) be
autonomous and be permitted to form cluster apex organizations with other CBOs.
Autonomous CBOs by means of social mobilization, skill training, increased
productivity, increased income, savings and investment would begin a process of
sustained growth at the local level. Such a process, which we have called Participatory
Development22 would be integrally linked with the emergence of a new consciousness of
empowerment. The poor can begin to take autonomous initiatives to improve their
material conditions of life. They would thus break out of the poverty nexus and shift from
being victims to active subjects of social and economic change. Such a process of village
level increases in productivity, incomes and savings would not only constitute a direct
attack on the poverty problem but would also contribute to a faster and more equitable
macro economic growth23
.
Such autonomous organizations of the poor could not only become a framework for
grassroots economic growth, but would also constitute countervailing power to that of the
22 The concept of Participatory Development is formulated in: Akmal Hussain: Pakistan, A Strategy
for Poverty Alleviation, Vanguard, Lahore, 1994, Pages 26 to 29.
Also see: P. Wignaraja, A. Hussain, H. Sethi & G. Wignaraja: Participatory Development:
Learning from South Asia, O.U.P, 1991.
23 For a more detailed discussion of this issue, See: Akmal Hussain: Poverty, Growth and
Governance, Chapter in, V.A. Pai Panandiker (ed.): Problems of Governance in South Asia,
Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi, 2000. 14
power structures of local elites. At the same time, these autonomous organizations of the
poor would enable the individual poor household to get better access over input and
output markets.
Facilitating the emergence of autonomous organizations of the poor particularly
organizations of poor women, could enable the newly established local government
institutions to function in a more equitable and effective manner. The equity would be
with respect to class as well as gender. This would require establishing institutionalized
links between autonomous organizations of the poor and local government bodies at the
Village, Union Council, Tehsil and District levels. These institutional links between
organizations of the poor and elected local bodies would enable more participatory and
equitable processes of project identification, design and implementation for local level
development.
II.3 Institutional Forms of Development NGOs
Over the last three decades the tightening financial constraints on the government24 and
growing awareness of the limitations of top-down development programmes to alleviate
poverty,25 have created the space for non-governmental organizations and alternative
approaches to development action. During this period a variety of NGOs have established
support programmes aimed at developing community organizations at the village level,
institution building, providing training and accessing credit and technical support.
Development NGOs exist in a variety of sizes and forms, from large centralized bodies
spanning a number of districts and provinces, such as the Rural Support Programs (RSPs)
to smaller organizations operating in a number of regions within the same province (such
as SUNGI). Finally there are CBOs which operate on a very local scale either at the
village level or a cluster village level.
24 The government’s annual development programme as a percentage of GDP has declined from
seven percent in the 1970s to 2.5 percent this year.
25 For a discussion on the limitations of top-down development programmes see: Akmal Hussain,
Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, op. cit., pages 23 –26.15
Development NGOs range from multi-functional ones that support a wide range of
activities in fields such as income generation, natural resource management and the social
sector, (e.g. PIEDAR, SUNGI and RSPs) to a particular limited set of operations such as
KASHF (which is essentially a micro-credit support NGO), or which target a particular
disadvantaged group such as women through innovative and multi sectoral interventions
(e.g. Shirkatgah, Aurat Foundation).
II.4 Taking small NGOs to Scale: Some Necessary Conditions for Success26
Some large NGOs such as AKRSP, PRSP and PPAF have achieved impressive results.
At the same time, in the case of other large government created NGOs such as the NRSP,
questions continue to remain with respect to five issues: (i) Lack of financial self
sufficiency and continuing dependence on government/donor support. (ii) The problem of
cost effectiveness. (iii) The problem of accuracy in targeting the poor population. (iv)
The problem of speed and scale of coverage of the poor population. (v) Lack of
autonomy of village level community organizations within the centralized command
structure of the NRSP27
.
The success and limitations of existing large government supported RSPs notwithstanding,
an approach of letting “a hundred flowers bloom”, may enable greater
innovation, rapid growth and success of the endeavour of development through NGOs.
In this sub-section we will examine some of the factors in the success of small NGOs
reaching scale.
First, apart from the efficacy of the Participatory Development methodology adopted by
some development NGOs, perhaps the single most important factor in their success is the
26 See, Akmal Hussain, Employment Generation, Poverty Alleviation and Growth in Pakistan’s
Rural Sector: Policies for Institutional Change, Report prepared for the ILO, Country Employment
Policy Review (CEPR), Pakistan, March 1999. pages 65 to 73.
27 (i) For a more detailed discussion of these issues, see, Akmal Hussain, et.al. UNDP-Pakistan
National Human Development Report 2003, Oxford University Press, Karachi 2003. chapter 4.
(ii) See, Akmal Hussain, Employment Generation, Poverty Alleviation and Growth in
Pakistan’s Rural Sector: Policies for Institutional Change, Report prepared for the ILO, Country
Employment Policy Review (CEPR), Pakistan, March 1999. pages 60 to 65. 16
quality of leadership. Specifically, it is the ability to relate with humility and love with
the poor. It is to build a team which while being internally coordinated, at the same time,
enables each member to become a centre of thought and action. The successful NGO
leader creates the team synergy to develop innovative responses to each new problem on
the ground. Yet, he/she ensures that each action by the team contributes to reinforcing the
process of the poor taking charge of their development. The effective leader focuses the
team to experience the potential of the poor and to grasp the specific dynamics of how
they can organize, take responsibilities and initiate change. Thus the challenge for the
NGO leadership is to so relate with the poor and the team, that every act, every word,
every moment of silence, contributes to fertilizing the other, rather than establishing
control: Liberating rather than inducing dependency.
The second factor in the success of small NGOs is the identification, training and
fostering of village level activists who gradually begin to manage existing COs, thereby,
enabling NGO staff to give more time to develop new COs. This process of devolution
of management responsibility from NGO staff to village level activists is a crucial factor
in the enlargement of NGO coverage in a situation where funds are limited and rapid
expansion of staff, financially infeasible. The converse of this dynamic is that if too
much money becomes available too early, it undermines discipline, initiative and energy
of the NGO.
The third factor in the success of small NGOs which have reached significant scale is the
development of second level management and the ability of top level leadership to
devolve responsibility, acknowledge their achievements and to learn from them just as
much as it is necessary for the leadership to learn from the poor. An inner wakefulness
that comes from transcending the ego is necessary to be always open to learning from the
poor, and from each member of one’s team. It is this openness to learning from others
that constitutes the basis of the organization’s dynamism, its innovation and its sense of
being a community.17
The fourth factor in the success of small NGOs in reaching significant scale is the
development of credible accounting procedures, and a regular monitoring and evaluation
exercise on the basis of which donor funding can be sought when it is required. In each
case the successful NGO, apart from devising efficacious modes of reflection and action
with the village communities, also develops formalized recording and reporting systems.
III. INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK FOR A SMALL AND MEDIUM
FARMER AGRICULTURE GROWTH STRATEGY28
Pakistan’s fragile democracy is threatened by an economic crisis combined with growing
poverty that fuels terrorist organizations. An important factor in the economic crisis is the
food deficit and the underlying stagnation in yields per acre of major crops. (In the year
2007-08, crop sector growth was negative). It can be argued that if the yield potential of
the medium and small size farm sector is achieved, occasional food shortages can be
converted into sustained food surpluses. Such a shift can enable Pakistan to convert its
weakness into its strength: The crippling economic burden of food imports (when they
are necessary) can be converted into a strength through food exports. To bring about this
transformation a new policy framework is required to shift from the earlier elite farmer
strategy to a new small farmer growth strategy.
The rural poor once liberated from the shackles of feudal power and provided with
ownership rights can become a major driving force in accelerating agriculture growth and
in achieving both political and economic democracy in Pakistan. In this section we will
first briefly argue the case for land reform in Pakistan today as a means of achieving
democracy at the political level and equitable growth at the economic level. We will then
discuss the policy option available to the government of transferring state owned land to
the landless peasantry together with an institutional framework for providing sustainable
livelihoods to about 58 percent of the existing tenant households.
28 This section is drawn from Akmal Hussain: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, Pakistan
Country Study for the SACEPS Poverty Project, 30th September 2008. chapter 4, pages 129 to
137. 18
III.1 Land Reforms for Sustainable Growth with Equity
At an economic level the existence of a powerful landed elite is indicated by the fact that
according to the Agriculture Census of 2000, as much as 30 percent of total farm area is
owned by land owners with ownership holdings above 50 acres, and yet they constitute
only 2 percent of the total number of land owners29. Elements of this landed elite
dominate the major political parties, local governments, institutions and markets for
credit and agriculture input distribution.
When the ‘Green Revolution’ technology became available in the late 1960s it was
possible to substantially accelerate agriculture growth through an elite farmer strategy
which concentrated the new inputs on large farms. At that time the crucial determinant in
yield differences became not the labour input per acre in which small family farms had
been at an advantage in earlier decades, but the application of the seed-water-fertilizer
package to which the large landlords with their greater financial power had superior
access. Thus the ‘Green Revolution’ had made it possible to accelerate agriculture growth
without having to bring about any real change in the rural power structure. Today, after
almost four decades of the elite farmer strategy, the imperative of land reform is reemerging,
albeit in a more complex form than before. As the large farms approach the
maximum yield per acre with the available technology, further growth in agricultural
output increasingly depends on raising the yield per acre of small farms and reversing the
trend of land degradation brought about by improper agricultural practices.
The small and medium farm sector whose yield potential remains to be fully utilized,
constitutes a substantial part of the agrarian economy. Farms below 25 acres constitute
about 94 percent of the total number of farms and about 60 percent of the total farm area.
29 These Agriculture Census figures of the share of large land owners are highly under estimated
because the Agriculture Census does not take account of the fact that a large number of individual
ownership holdings may be nominally under the names of individual family members or even
servants (to avoid the legal ceiling on individual ownership holding) but are actually owned by the
head of the family. According to an earlier estimate of the share of land owning families as much
as 30 percent of total farm area was owned by land owners in the over 150 acres category who
constituted less than 0.1 percent of the total number of land owners. (See, Akmal Hussain,
Pakistan: Land Reforms Reconsidered, chapter in Hamza Alavi and John Harriss (eds), Sociology
of “Developing Societies” South Asia, Macmillan, London, 1989. 19
From the viewpoint of raising the yield per acre of small and medium farms (i.e. farms of
less than 25 acres) the critical consideration is that 15.7 percent of the total farm area in
the less than 25 acre farm category is operated by landless tenants. Another 13.07 percent
of the farm acreage in less than 25 acre farms is operated by owner cum tenant farmers.
Since tenants lose half of any increase in output to the landlord, they lack the incentive to
invest in technology which could raise yields per acre. Because of their weak financial
and social position they also lack the ability to make such investments. Their ability to
invest is further eroded by a nexus of social and economic dependence on the landlord
which deprives the tenant of much of his investible surplus.
This problem is further exacerbated by the absence of an efficient land market where
productive land can move to the more efficient operator. Flexible and secure tenancy
contracts, and a competitive land market which can allow efficient operation of farm
land, can only emerge if the extra economic power currently enjoyed by the landed elite
is constrained. Thus the objective of raising yields in the small farm sector is inseparable
from removing the constraints to growth arising out of the institutional structure of
tenancy. A policy initiative that enables the tenant to acquire land is therefore an essential
first step in providing the small farmers with both the incentive and the ability to raise
their yields/acre.
Thus the imperative of land reform today arises not only from the need to accelerate
agricultural growth and alleviate rural poverty, but also from the need to build a
sustainable democracy. A society based on tolerance, merit and the supremacy of law
would require overcoming feudal forms in the conditions of production, in society, and in
the very functioning of the State.
III.2 Land for the Landless
A policy of enabling tenant farm households to acquire ownership rights together with
access to the markets for inputs could play a vital role in making the small farm sector the
leading edge of a faster and more equitable agriculture growth. Such a policy could have
two main elements: (a) Transferring the existing 2.6 million acres of state owned land to 20
landless peasants together with an institutional framework for providing them with access
over high quality seeds, fertilizers, water and extension services. (b) Institutional changes
to open up the land market together with the provision of credit to tenant farm households
for enabling them to purchase land. Let us briefly discuss each of these policies in turn.
III.3 State Land for the Landless
An initial step in providing productive assets to the rural poor could be to allot the
available 2.6 million acres of State owned land to the landless. This cannot be seen as a
substitute for a land reform programme of ‘land to the tiller’. According to the Census of
Agriculture 2000, there are about 4.97 million acres of private farm area under pure
tenant cultivation in farms below 25 acres. It is this acreage that would need to pass into
peasant ownership for a genuine land reform to occur. Nevertheless 2.6 million acres
(assuming that all of it is cultivable) could make a significant contribution to the
reduction of rural poverty. For example if the 2.6 million acres of state owned land were
to be transferred to landless farm households in holdings of 5 acres each, then as many as
520,000 tenant farmers would become owner operators. This means that out of the total
number of tenant farmers (about 897,000) in the less than 25 acre category, as many as
about 58% would become owner operators.
However, it is important to recognize that providing ownership of land to the landless is a
necessary but not a sufficient condition for alleviating their poverty. Enabling the
landless to make the transferred land cultivable, to actually settle on the new land and to
achieve a sustainable increase in their income, productivity and savings are equally
important factors in making the scheme successful.
The achievement of sustainable livelihoods for the landless rural poor through the
provision of state owned land would involve the following steps to be undertaken by
relevant departments of provincial governments in partnership with NGOs, private sector
and international donor agencies30:
30 This sub-section is based on a policy note contributed by the author to the Ministry of Local
Government and Rural Development: Akmal Hussain, Overcoming Poverty Through Providing
Land to the Landless, Note submitted to the Ministry of Local Government and Rural
Development (Mimeo), April 30, 2001.21
1. Undertake a diagnostic survey of the areas in which the beneficiaries and the
lands to be transferred to them are located. The objectives of these diagnostic
surveys would be:
(a) To evaluate the cultivable status of the land and the potential uses for
which the land could be utilized.
(b) Identification of the main physical constraints to utilizing the land for the
purpose of achieving a sustainable livelihood for the poor. (Examples of
such constraints are: saline soils, poor quality of ground water, poor
management of torrent water or an absolute non availability of irrigation
water).
(c) Identification of physical infrastructure interventions that could be made
through participatory development projects involving partnership between
government departments, NGOs and organizations of the landless poor in
the concerned areas (examples of such interventions could be, minor land
forming and land reclamation schemes, provision of tube wells where
possible, check dams, water lifting devices and water harvesting schemes).
(d) Identification of micro enterprise projects which individual households or
groups of households of the poor could undertake in order to achieve a
diversified economic base for their livelihoods. For the identification of
such micro enterprise schemes the survey would involve consultations
with organizations of the poor and with individual poor households from
amongst the potential beneficiaries.
(e) Estimates of credit needs of those poor households who are targeted as
beneficiaries of the newly allotted lands.
(f) Socio economic profiles of the landless poor in the specific areas where
they are expected to acquire the land under the scheme. This profile would
identify the mechanisms through which poverty of the concerned 22
households is reproduced, their current major sources of income, debt and
actual or potential skills.
2. The provincial governments would facilitate the local governments in the specific
areas where the relevant state lands are located to initiate a process of social
mobilization of the landless poor. This mobilization would be essential to
enabling the landless poor households to begin using the newly acquired land in a
productive way and to position themselves for acquiring skill training, credit and
technical support from both government departments and NGOs.
This social mobilization could be conducted by local governments through
partnership with community based organizations at the local level, NGOs at the
district and provincial levels and with support from apex organizations such as the
Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund and also from donor agencies.
3. Training of social mobilisers/catalysts could be undertaken by specialized NGOs
such as the South Asia Partnership, NRSP, PRSP and SAPNA (South Asian
Perspective for new Alternatives).
4. After specific local level infrastructure projects for improving the productivity of
state allotted lands have been identified, the provincial governments in
collaboration with Pakistan Agricultural Research Council could mobilize the
technical expertise for implementing the projects through organizations of the
poor. The financial resources necessary for these infrastructure projects could be
mobilized from Asian Development Bank, World Bank, Small Business Finance
Corporation, The Khushhali Bank, Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund.
5. The provision of technical training and credit for micro enterprise projects could
be undertaken by networking the following organizations: (a) PPAF and
Khushhali Bank for credit. (b) For organizing technical training and technical
support for micro enterprise projects of the poor the following organizations could
be networked: NGO Federation (BINGOF), Punjab NGO Coordination Council, 23
Sarhad NGO Ittehad, Sind NGO Federation, the Pakistan NGO Forum and
SUNGI.
The scheme of providing state lands to the landless poor can lead to a sustainable
increase in incomes of the beneficiaries if the provision of state land is combined with the
following elements: (1) social organization of the poor, (2) development of local
infrastructure for increasing land productivity, (3) development of micro enterprise
projects of the poor and (4) provision of training, technical support and micro credit to
the poor in order to develop a diversified economic base for overcoming their poverty. If
such a scheme for participatory development of poor landless households could be
undertaken then the government could set a new example not only for Pakistan but for
developing countries as a whole, that could demonstrate how the landless poor can be
enabled to overcome their poverty.
III.4 Enabling Tenant Households to Buy Land
While the transfer of state owned land (2.6 million acres) could provide land to 58
percent of the existing tenant farmers, the remaining 42 percent could be enabled to buy
land through credit and institutional changes in the land market. Thus all the existing
tenant households could become owner operators who could play a strategic role in
generating a faster and more equitable agriculture growth.
Out of a total of 897,000 pure tenant farmers, 377,000 households could be enabled to
acquire ownership rights over 5 acre farms through purchase of land. This would create
the institutional basis of providing both the incentive and the ability for tenant farmers to
increase yields per acre. This objective could be achieved through four sets of policy
actions:
(a) Through a consortium of government, donors and commercial banks a
credit fund for providing land to the landless amounting to about Rs.332
billion (USD 4.24 billion) could be created. The purpose would be to: (i)
provide targeted credit to enable about 377,000 tenant farm households to
purchase 5 acres per household of cultivable land with a total cost of 24
approximately Rs.283 billion (USD 3.62 billion), (ii) allocate Rs.50 billion
(USD 0.64 billion) for follow up extension services to enable efficient
cultivation of purchased land.
(b) Update, systematize and computerize the land revenue records. The
objective would be to establish clear ownership rights of existing
owners/claimants such that owned land could become legally transferable
without the market transactions being subject to crippling litigation.
(c) Facilitate the formation of small farmer associations at the union council
and tehsil levels with a view to providing small farmers with the leverage
to get equitable access over the markets for seed, fertilizer, tube well water
and pesticides. At the moment markets for these inputs are asymmetric
with respect to the large and small farmers respectively. Local power
structures mediate local markets so that the small farmers get poorer
quality of seeds, fertilizer and pesticides, and have to pay relatively high
prices for these inputs compared to the large farmers.
(d) Strengthen extension service organizations of the Ministry of Rural
Development at the union council and tehsil levels and re-orient their
operations to provide high quality support to small farmers for: (i) soil
testing to enable the farmer to determine the precise composition of the
chemical fertilizers that is congruent with the nutrient requirements of the
soil, (ii) improved on farm water management to increase water use
efficiency, (iii) improved agricultural practices based on new scientific
knowledge to reduce salinity and improve the organic profile of the top
soil.
III.5 Sustaining Small Farmer Growth through the Small Farmer Development
Corporation (SFDC)
The institutional framework for a small farmer led agriculture growth strategy could be to
establish a Small Farmer Development Corporation (SFDC) in which farmers operating
below 25 acres of land could have the opportunity of becoming shareholders. The 25
following types of farmers could be eligible to become shareholders of such a
corporation:
a) All those who will receive state owned land or have in the past received state
owned land.
b) All owner farmers, owner-cum-tenant farmers and pure tenant farmers
operating less than 25 acres of land could also be offered equity stakes in the
SFDC.
III.5.1 How to float the SFDC
One way of floating the SFDC is for the PPAF to sponsor the establishment of the SFDC
while ensuring that the ownership and control of the corporation lies with the small
farmer shareholders.
III.5.2 How to Provide Equity to Small Farmers
The PPAF out of its own resources or by accessing donor funds, provide to the
recipients of the 2.6 million acres state owned land, a loan of Rs.65 billion to the
520,000 small farmers who are recipients of 5 acre packages of land. Each such
small farmer would get Rs.125,000 as a loan to be invested in the SFDC.
This loan should be deposited in the corporation as equity of Rs.25000 per acre of
owned land by the recipients of State land, i.e. Rs.125,000 per five acre package.
Small farmers who are not recipients of state land should also be enabled to
become shareholders in the SFDC.
III.5.3 The Organizational Functions of the SFDC
The equity could be leveraged to acquire loans from the domestic commercial banking
sector as well as from the World Bank and ADB to be used for:
(a) Land Development of the land operated by the shareholders.
(b) Provision of extension services to the shareholder farmers for: 26
(i) Improving the quality of top soils.
(ii) Efficient on-farm water management through laser based land
leveling for accurate gradient, improved water channels and
where required, drip irrigation.
(iii) Shifting to high value added crops through innovative
techniques such as tunnel farming and also dairy farming and
livestock development.
(c) Provision of loans to farmers for purchase of inputs, and investments
in improving the on-farm water management.
(d) Recent research has shown that rural markets for agriculture outputs
and inputs in Pakistan are asymmetric with respect to the large and
small farmers31. The SFDC could serve to provide more equitable
market access to small farmers by facilitating purchase of high quality
inputs and arranging marketing of agriculture products.
(e) Investment on behalf of small farmers in agro processing industrial
units such as grain milling, cotton gins and oil presses. These
investments could be under written by organizations such as PPAF,
Khushali Bank, Small Business Finance Corporation as well as aid
donors32
.
III.5.4 Broad Basing Equity to include all Small Farmers
Those small farmers who are not recipients of State owned land and wish to become
shareholders in the SFDC can be provided loans of upto Rs.25000 per owned acre which
would be automatically deposited in the corporation as their equity. The loans would be
paid back from the dividend earnings of the equity under the loan agreement.
IV. INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK FOR FASTER GROWTH OF SMALL
SCALE INDUSTRIAL ENTERPRISES (SSEs)33
.
Since small scale industries have higher employment elasticities, smaller Incremental
Capital Output Ratios (ICORs), and shorter gestation periods. Therefore an increased
share of investment in this sector could enable both a higher GDP growth for given levels
31 Akmal Hussain, Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, Pakistan Country Study for the SACEPS
Poverty Project, 2008. (Forthcoming)
32 We are grateful to Professor Rehman Sobhan, President of Grameen Bank and Chairman, Centre
for Policy Dialogue, Dhaka for this suggestion.
33 This section has been drawn from Akmal Hussain: Poverty, Power and Economic Growth,
Pakistan Country Study for the SACEPS Poverty Project, 30th September 2008. pages 115 to 119. 27
of investment as well as higher employment generation for given levels of growth. At the
same time if the institutional conditions could be created for enabling small scale
industries to move into high value added components for both import substitution in the
domestic market and for exports, Pakistan’s balance of payments pressures could be
eased. The key strategic issue in accelerating the growth of SSEs is to enable them to
shift to the high value added, high growth end of the product market. These SSEs include
high value added units in light engineering, automotive parts, moulds, dyes, machine
tools and electronics and computer software.
Training of a large number of software experts with requisite support in credit and
marketing could quickly induce a significant increase in software exports from Pakistan.
Pakistan could build a pool of software experts for a large increase in export earnings.
This would of course require a proactive government to establish joint ventures between
large software companies such as Microsoft and Pakistan’s private sector institutions
such as LUMS and INFORMATICS. The Ministry of Science and Technology is already
moving rapidly in facilitating the growth of information technology in Pakistan. In this
sub-section however we will focus on small scale manufacturing enterprises.
A large number of small scale enterprises (SSEs) in the Punjab and the North Western
Frontier Province (NWFP) have a considerable potential for growth and high value added
production such as components for engineering goods or components of high quality
farm implements for the large scale manufacturing sector.34 Yet they are in many cases
producing low value added items like steel shutters or car exhaust pipes resulting in low
profitability, low savings and slow growth.
IV.1 Constraints to the Rapid Growth of SSEs
Small scale enterprises in small towns of Pakistan face the following major constraints:
(i) Inability of small units to get vending contracts for the manufacture of
components from the large-scale manufacturing sector (LSM).
34 Akmal Hussain: Labour Absorption in Pakistan’s Rural Sector, Final Report, ILO/ARTEP
(Mimeo), 20th September 1989, Pages 21 to 23.28
(ii) Due to lack of expertise in production management and the frequent
inability to achieve quality control it becomes difficult to meet tight
delivery schedules.
(iii) Lack of specific skills like advanced mill work, metal fabrication,
precision welding, all of which are needed for producing quality products
with low tolerances and precise dimensional control. In other cases
accounting and management skills may be inadequate.
(iv) Difficulty faced by small units in getting good quality raw materials,
which often can only be ordered in bulk (for which the small entrepreneurs
do not have the working capital), and from distant large cities.
(v) Lack of specialized equipment.
(vi) Absence of fabrication facilities such as forging, heat treatment and
surface treatment which are required for manufacture of high value added
products, but are too expensive for any one small unit to set up.
(vii) Lack of capital for investment and absence of credit facilities.
IV.2 Overcoming the Constraints to the Growth of SSEs
Overcoming the aforementioned constraints would involve providing institutional support
in terms of credit, quality control management, skill training and marketing. This could
be done by facilitating the establishment of Common Facilities Centers (CFCs) located in
the specified growth nodes in selected towns where the entrepreneurial and technical
potential as well as markets already exist. Such support institutions (CFCs) while being
facilitated by the government and autonomous organizations such as SMEDA can and
should be in the private sector and market driven.
The concept of the Common Facilities Centers is based on the fact that small scale
industrialists in Pakistan have already demonstrated a high degree of entrepreneurship, 29
innovation and efficient utilization of capital. The CFCs would provide an opportunity
for rapid growth to SSEs through local participation in extension services, prototype
development, and diffusion of improved technologies, equipment, and management
procedures. The CFCs would constitute a decentralized system which ensures continuous
easy access to a comprehensive package of support services such as credit, skill training,
managerial advice and technical assistance. The CFCs could also be linked up with
national research centres, and donor, agencies for drawing upon technical expertise and
financial resources of these agencies in the service of small scale industries (SSI).
The Common Facilities Centres could have the following functional dimensions:
(i) Marketing
Provision of orders from the large scale manufacturing sector for components, and
from farmers for farm implements. These orders would then be sub-contracted to
the cluster of SSI units that the CFC is supposed to serve. The individual order
would be sub-contracted to the SSI on the basis of the skills and potential
strengths of the unit concerned.
(ii) Monitoring and Quality Control
Having given the sub-contract, the CFC would then monitor the units closely and
help pinpoint and overcome unit specific bottlenecks to ensure timely delivery
and quality control of the manufactured products. These bottlenecks may be
specialized skills, equipment, good quality raw material or credit.
(iii) Skill Training and Product Development.
Skill training for technicians could be provided by the new good quality
vocational training institutes (VTIs) established by the Vocational Training
Council of Punjab. Similar VTIs could be established in other provinces. The
CFC would provide specialized supplementary skill training on its premises to
workers in the satellite SSI units when required. At the same time, it would
provide advice on jigs, fixtures, special tools and product development where
required.30
(iv) Forging and Heat Treatment Facilities
The CFCs would establish at their premises plants for forging, heat treatment and
surface treatment. The SSI units could come to the CFC to get such fabrication
done on the products they are manufacturing on sub-contract, and pay a mutually
agreed price for this job to the CFC.
(v) Credit
The CFC would provide credit to the SSEs for purchase of new equipment and
raw materials. In cases where raw materials are available in bulk supply, the CFC
could buy it from the source, stock it on its premises and sell at a reasonable price
to units as and when they need them.
V. INCLUSIVE GROWTH THROUGH EQUITY STAKES FOR THE POOR
IN LARGE CORPORATIONS
The hallmark of underdevelopment or what North calls a Limited Access Social Order, is
an institutional structure which systematically excludes the majority of the people from
the process of investment, economic growth and access over basic services for human
development35. If economic growth and political democracy are to be sustainable it is
necessary to move towards an institutional framework which provides opportunities to all
of the people rather than a small elite to participate in the process of investment, growth
and human development. In this section we will examine some of the innovative new
institutional forms that have been tried and tested in a number of South Asian countries
for mainstreaming the poor into the economy.
Apart from recent work by Muhammad Yunus and Rehman Sobhan respectively, the
concept of enabling ownership rights to the poor in the mainstream large scale corporate
sector has not yet been adequately addressed in the literature on development policy36
.
35 Douglass C. North, John Joseph Wallis and Barry R. Weingast, Violence and Social Orders: A
Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge University Press,
July 19, 2008 (Forthcoming).
36 (i) Muhammad Yunus, Creating a World Without Poverty: Social Business and the Future of
Capitalism, Public Affairs (A Member of the Perseus Books Group), USA, 2007. 31
The poor can be included in the process of investment and economic growth not merely
through micro enterprises, but can be engaged into the mainstream corporate sector as
well.
V.1 Financing the Entry of the Poor into the Capital Market
Investments in the capital market have often been made by pledging the stocks being
purchased. A down payment of say 20 percent of the value of the asset is usually made by
the investor and the residual amount of the stock purchased is covered by the bank which
then holds the stock as collateral.
There is no reason why such loan financing for under writing investment in the capital
market should not be made available to organizations of the poor. Their small savings can
be pooled and then used as down payments on investments in the corporate sector. The
poor can thereby become eligible for bank loans to buy into the initial public offering
(IPO) by the corporate sector. They can also be directly inducted as equity partners in
existing large corporations.
There are clearly issues of risk assessment and risk reduction, as well as how such groups
of the poor can be mobilized into sufficient numbers to empower them to become
partners in the corporate sector. The methodology of group formation of the poor and its
dynamics, have been discussed in section-II.
VI. SOME STRATEGIC INITIATIVES TO ACHIEVE GROWTH BY THE
POOR AND FOR THE POOR
There are three sectors which have considerable potential for stimulating GDP growth,
poverty reduction and increasing Pakistan’s foreign exchange earnings: (i) Milk and dairy
products, (ii) Livestock and the production of meat and meat products, (iii) Marine
fisheries. In this section we will briefly discuss the institutional form that can be deployed
in the case of milk and dairy products on the basis of public private partnership to
establish corporate enterprises with equity stakes for the poor. Similar institutional
(ii) Rehman Sobhan, Challenging the Injustice of Poverty: Agendas for Inclusive Development in
South Asia, SAGE Press, New Delhi, 2010. 32
structures can be established for livestock and production of meat, and for marine
fisheries.
Milk Production Potential of Poor Peasants. With over 177 billion rupees worth of milk
being produced annually in Pakistan, milk is Pakistan’s largest product in the agriculture
sector. Unlike agriculture crops the production of milk can be accelerated sharply within
a couple of years. Currently Pakistan’s milch cattle yield per animal is one fifth the
European average. Demonstrable experience in the field has shown that the milk yield per
animal in Pakistan can be doubled within two years through scientific feeding, breeding
and marketing. What is required is an institutional framework for training the farmers in
scientific feeding and breeding, and for establishing the logistics to collect milk from the
farm door by means of refrigerated transport, domestic marketing as well as
arrangements for refrigerated storage at airports and subsequent airfreight to export
markets. Such an initiative could have a significant impact not only on the incomes of
poor peasants but also on exports and overall GDP growth37
.
Marine Fisheries Potential and Constraints. Marine Fisheries, also provide a significant
potential for improving foreign exchange earnings although not as large as the potential
for milk. Here again, what is required is improved institutional support and better
management rather than huge investments by the Government. The expansion in the
export of marine fisheries is constrained because the storage facilities for transportation
do not match the international quality standards. Currently alternate layers of fish and
hard sharp edged ice are placed in containers on the boats. Under the weight of upper
layers of fish and the sharp edged ice, fish in the lower layers are crushed, and the
resultant bleeding causes putrefaction. To avoid this, it is necessary to provide shelves for
layered storage of fish in boats, topped by dry ice, with fiberglass covers to maintain the
European Union standards of minus 7oC temperature during transportation. An export
37 Akmal Hussain, A Policy for Pro Poor Growth, paper in Towards Pro Poor Growth Policies in
Pakistan, Proceedings of the Pro-Poor Growth Policies Symposium, 17th March 2003, UNDPPIDE,
Islamabad. page 72.33
potential of 300 million dollars exists over the next three years if such improved
management of the marine fisheries industry could be achieved38
.
Proposed Institutional Structure for Milk and Milk Products. It is proposed that the
Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (PPAF), its NGO partner organizations at the district
level and provincial Dairy Development Boards be brought together into a consortium to
establish a Pakistan Dairy Corporation (PDC). The institutional framework for the PDC
could be as follows:
This corporation should be a public limited company, run by a professional
management with poor peasants as its shareholders.
International donors and the government of Pakistan can contribute to establishing
a special fund within the PPAF which can be used to give either grants or loans to
poor peasants to enable them to buy the equity in the PDC and also to acquire
additional milch animals.
The objective of the corporation should be to generate profits through establishing
milk collection centers in each Union Council to collect milk, from its
shareholders, arrange refrigerated transport, establish milk pasteurizing and
packaging facilities at the provincial level, and a marketing and export
infrastructure.
The PDC should also establish an infrastructure at the village level for directly
collecting milk from poor peasant milk producing shareholders, testing the milk
and immediate payment to the milk producers.
A computerized data base platform should be established at the Union Council
level to keep a record of the profile of each milk producer with respect to the
following data: percentage of milk that passes the quality test; payments for milk
supplied; extension services provided; increases in yields per milch animal;
38 Ibid. page 73. 34
changes in the stock of milch animal, initial level of and changes in household
income resulting from increased milk sales.
The profits of the corporation should be used partly for re-investment and growth
and partly for disbursing dividends to the poor peasant shareholders.
The PPAF should develop new partner organizations at the Union Council, Tehsil
and District levels which would be exclusively devoted to forming special
purpose community organizations (COs) of poor peasants. The objective of the
COs would be to enable its members to increase production and sale of milk,
access credit for increasing the stock of milk animals at the household level and
undertake scientific feeding and breeding of milch animals for increasing milk
yields.
The PPAF could also be tasked to provide credit to the milk producing share
holders of PDC, arrange for extension services to the community organizations of
milk producers for testing and inoculating animals against disease and scientific
feeding and breeding practices.
CONCLUSION
In the ongoing struggle against militant extremism and the process of building democracy
the economic dimension is a vital element. Establishing the institutional structure for
inclusive growth in which the people of Pakistan could participate in the process of
growth would enable a higher and at the same time, sustained growth with equity.
An essential feature of inclusive growth is to provide access to the poor over productive
assets through a variety of institutional mechanisms so that they can become both the
subjects as well as the beneficiaries of growth. In this context four main institutional
mechanisms were discussed: (i) A process of localized capital accumulation involving
micro enterprise development, sustainable livelihoods and local infrastructure
construction through the Participatory Development methodology. (ii) A small and
medium farmer strategy for accelerated growth through the provision of land ownership 35
rights to the landless with supportive institutional mechanisms for increasing yields per
acre. (iii) Accelerated growth of small and medium scale industrial enterprises through an
institutional framework for increasing production and export of high value added goods
in high growth sectors. (iv) Provision of productive assets to the poor through equity
stakes in large corporations owned by the poor and managed by professionals in the fields
of milk production, livestock, and marine fisheries.
The institutional structure for inclusive growth would enable growth through the
provision of economic citizenship to the people of Pakistan and thereby constitute a vital
element in strengthening democracy. 36
REFERENCES
1. Hussain, Akmal, et.al. 2003. Poverty, Growth and Governance, Pakistan National
Human Development Report 2003, UNDP, Oxford University Press, Karachi.
2. Hussain, Akmal. 1989. Labour Absorption in Pakistan’s Rural Sector, Final
Report, ILO/ARTEP (Mimeo).
3. Hussain, Akmal. 1989. Land Reforms Reconsidered, in Hamza Alavi and John
Harriss (eds.): South Asia, Macmillan Education Ltd., London.
4. Hussain, Akmal. 1994. Poverty Alleviation in Pakistan, Vanguard Books, Lahore.
5. Hussain, Akmal. 1998. Punjab Rural Support Programme (PRSP), The First Four
Months, Report to the Board of Directors of PRSP.
6. Hussain, Akmal. 1999. Employment Generation, Poverty Alleviation and Growth
in Pakistan’s Rural Sector: Policies for Institutional Change, ILO, Country
Employment Policy Review (CEPR), Pakistan, (Mimeo).
7. Hussain, Akmal. 2000. Poverty, Growth and Governance, chapter in, V.A. Pai
Panandiker (ed.): Problems of Governance in South Asia, Centre for Policy
Research, New Delhi.
8. Hussain, Akmal. 2001. Overcoming Poverty Through Providing Land to the
Landless, Note submitted to the Ministry of Local Government and Rural
Development (Mimeo).
9. Hussain, Akmal. 2003. A Policy for Pro Poor Growth, paper in Towards Pro Poor
Growth Policies in Pakistan, Proceedings of the Pro-Poor Growth Policies
Symposium, March 17, 2003, UNDP-PIDE, Islamabad.
10. Hussain, Akmal. 2008. Poverty, Power and Economic Growth, Pakistan Country
Study for the SACEPS Poverty Project, (Forthcoming).
11. Hussain, Akmal. 2010. Report of the Working Group on Poverty Reduction
Strategy and Human Resource Development, Planning Commission, Government
of Pakistan, Islamabad.
12. North, Douglass C. 2004. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic
Performance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, England.
13. North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change,
Princeton University Press.37
14. North, Douglass C., Wallis, John Joseph, Weingast, Barry R. 2008. Violence and
Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human
History, Cambridge University Press, (Forthcoming).
15. Sobhan, Rehman. 2010. Challenging the Injustice of Poverty: Agendas for
Inclusive Development in South Asia, SAGE Press, New Delhi.
16. Wignaraja, Ponna, Hussain, Akmal, Sethi, Harsh and Wignaraja, Ganeshan. 1991.
Participatory Development, Learning from South Asia, United Nations Press,
Tokyo and Oxford University Press, Karachi.
17. Wignaraja, Ponna and Sirivardana, Susil. 2004. Pro-Poor Growth and Governance
in South Asia: Decentralization and Participatory Development, SAGE
Publications, New Delhi and London.
18. Wignaraja, Ponna, Sirivardana, Susil, Hussain, Akmal, (eds). 2009. Economic
Democracy through Pro Poor Growth, SAGE Publications, Delhi.
19. Yunus, Muhammad. 2007. Creating a World Without Poverty: Social Business
and the Future of Capitalism, Public Affairs (A Member of the Perseus Books
Group), USA.
- - - - - - - - - - - - - -
No comments:
Post a Comment