2
Economic Growth,
Poverty and The Child*
INTRODUCTION
In spite of rapid economic growth in many Third
World countries, a disturbingly high rate of death
due to child malnutrition continues. The physical
growth of large numbers of surviving children is
stunted, and in the case of even larger numbers the
possibilities of their creative growth are inhibited as
they get pushed into labour at a tender age. In this
paper I will very briefly attempt to indicate the
relationship between economic growth, poverty and
the plight of Third World children. In section-i are
presented some of the facts of child malnutrition. It is
argued that adoption of scientific methods to deal with
the problem are severely cons trained by the acute
poverty of the families concerned. Thus the problem is
essentially one of access rather than availability. In
section-2, I discuss the mechanism of poverty with
special reference to Pakistan. Finally, in
* This chapter is based on a paper presented by the author at the
HARVARD CONFERENCE ON WHO SPEAKS FOR THE CHILD,
Harvard University, Cambridge Mass. 11, 12, August 1986. Section -3 are presented in highly summarized form
some of the evidence from a child labour survey I
conducted in Lahore recently.
1. THE LEVEL OF CHILD MALNUTRITION
The process of economic growth in many Third
World countries is accompanied by growing
poverty. The impact of economic (1eprIV in poor
families is clearly greatest in the case of children
since they are more vulnerable than their adult
counterparts: More than 40,000 children die every
day from malnutrition and infection.1
For every one
of the children who have died, six now live in
hunger and ill health which permanently affects
their physical and mental growth2
.
In spite of the develop of technology and the
productive capacity to prevent child malnutrition,
progress towards reducing these mortality rates has
actually slowed down since the 1970’s. The
deterioration in the condition of children in recent
years is closely related t the growing
impoverishment emanating from the economic
growth process in many countries of the Third
World. Overall, the percentage of the world’s
children with inadequate food, water and health
care, which had been declining in the period
between 1945 and the early 1970’s is now likely to
remain the same at the end of this century as it is
today. The UN’s Food and Agriculture
Organization predicts that on the basis of present
trends, by the year 2000 there would he ‘‘a horrifying
increase in the numbers of the seriously undernourished
to some 600 to 650 millions.’’ It means a
30% increase ii the number of malnutritioned children
over the next 15 years.
11. POVERTY AND UNDERDEVELOPMENT
The impact of the available scientific advances on
Child Malnutrition is severely constrained by the lack of
access over food arising from poverty and
unemployment. Approximately one third of the
families whose children are malnourished fall into the
category of the poor, and poverty is being
systematically generated by a growth process in which
private profitability often comes into conflict with
social need. The economic structures in most Third
World countries are such that industrial growth is
inhibited. Whatever industrial growth does occur, is
characterized by increasingly capital - intensive
technologies, and income distribution between capital
and labour is shifting in favour of the former and the
employment generation capacity in industry is growing
at a far slower rate than the labour force. In agriculture
where the large majority of the population of the r1
World seeks its living, the growth of capitalist farming
while increasing agriculture output rapidly is
accompanied by growing landlessness, poverty and
unemployment.
Pakistan is a classic example of a capitalist under
developed country which has experienced rising
poverty and inequality during its periods of rapid
growth in GNP. Thus for example, during the decade
of the 1960’s when the economy registered an
impressive aggregate growth rate of 5% per annum,
the majority of the population suffered an absolute
decline in its living standard, for example, the capita
consumption of the poorest 60% of the urban
population declined from an index of 100 in 1963-64
to 96.1 in l969-705. The decline was even greater in the
case of the poorest 60% of the rural population whose
per capita food grain consumption declined from an
index of 100 in 1963-64 to only 91 in 1969-706
. There
was an even larger decline in real wages in industry.
For example, Griffin suggests that in the decade and a
half ending in 1967, real wages in large scale
manufacturing industry declined by 25%.7 More recently in the period 1976 to 1981, there was
once again rapid aggregate economic growth of over
6% per annum. In industry over 12% per annum
growth was registered, yet there was a sharp
deterioration in labour’s share of national income
alongwith a decline in the employment generation
capacity of the industrial sector. This is indicated by
the fact that labour’s share in value added declined at
the rate of 5.5% over the period 1976-81, and the
capital labour ratio increased at the rate of 11% over
the period..8
Just as industrial growth in Pakistan was accompanied
by growing inequality and a declining employment
generation capability, agriculture growth was
accompanied by increasing poverty, landlessness and
reduced labour absorption capacity in the rural sector.
We find that the so-called Green Revolution while it
generated an impressive increase in agriculture output,
induced large landlords to resume land for owner
cultivation on large mechanized farms. The result was
increased landlessness and an absolute decline in the
quantity and quality of diet of the poor peasantry.
During the period of the Green Revolution 0.79 million
peasants were displaced and converted into landless
labourers, which constituted almost 43% of agricultural
labourers in 1973g. The deterioration in the quantity and
quality of diet of the poor peasantry over the period is
illustrated by the following table 1.
The table shows that a significant proportion of the
poor peasantry suffered a decline in its level and
quality of food consumption precisely during a
period when overall food output was rising rapidly.
The reason why agricultural growth in Pakistan was
accompanied by increased poverty and
unemployment was because of the nature of the
agrarian structure into which the Green Revolution
technology was introduced; It was a situation where there was a high degree of
concentration of land ownership (30% of farm area
being owned by less than 0.5% of landowners).
Large landlords had traditionally rented out their
land to small tenants. When the new technology
became available, making owner cultivation highly
profitable, landowners began to resume land for
owner cultivation on large farms using mechanized
techniques. There is now evidence to suggest that
the rapid pace of labour displacing mechanization
by capitalist farmers is essentially for the purpose
of increasing control over the production process.
My study on labour absorption in Pakistan’s
agriculture10 suggests that if present trends in farm
mechanization continue, labour absorption capacity in
agriculture would decline by 6.9 million households by
the year 2002” On the other hand if tractor adoption
slows down by 50% and the land potential realized,
there can be an increase in labour absorption in
agriculture by about 20 million households over the next
15 years. Thus whether agriculture growth creates
employment or unemployment would essentially
depend on whether or not a re-distribution of
landownership is achieved and thereby a change in
agrarian structure. A more equitable distribution of
landownership in agriculture would by enabling a more
intensive use of land, accelerate overall food out put,
and at the same time achieve greater access to food for
the poor sections of rural society.
III. CHILD WORK AND POVERTY
Our discussion in the preceding sections has
proposed that the phenomenon of malnutrition
amongst children is intimately linked with the
phenomenon of poverty. The latter in turn is the
systematic consequence of a particular form of
economic growth based on a highly unequal
distribution of productive assets. In Pakistan, as in many other developing countries, the response to
poverty in many families is that children go out to
work. Child Work in many cases represents the will
of the child to survive in a social system that has
forsaken them. I attempted to collect data on child
work in terms of a wide range of economic and
social indicators. Due to limited resources I was
obliged however to use a very small sample. So
while the statistical evidence cannot claim
generality for the entire country, it is indicative of
the condition of child workers in the urban centres.
It may also be useful for further research since this
is the first time that data has been systematically
collected on Child Work in Pakistan.
The evidence suggests that in most professions, child
workers contribute a substantial proportion of total
family income and are hence obliged to work because
of the poverty pressure in the family i.e. in order to start
supplementing family income at an early age. (See
Table 2).
The pressure to supplement family income can be
gauged, by the fact that child workers are prepared to
work typically 54 to 72 hours a week for a pittance;
The average monthly income (cash plus benefits) is
approximately US$ 20. The working hours of
children are longer than their adult counterparts. This
is partly because their low wage rate obliges them to
work longer to get anything at all, and partly because
the employer feels he can pressurize younger workers
to work long hours more successfully than he can
adult workers.
It is interesting that although most of the child
workers are uneducated, (Table. 4), nevertheless an
overwhelming proportion of them wish to acquire an
education and consider it useful. This is another
indicator of the pressures of the family that obliges
children to work at an age when they would rather be at school.
Education for many of the child workers also meant
an opportunity for leisure and play which they are
deprived of due to their work. Typically child
workers get an opportunity to play 3 times per
month, and some can play only once a month
(Table-6).
Most child workers interviewed preferred to
continue with their existing jobs even though it was
extremely poorly paid, and involved long hours of
work in a hazardous work environment. This is
because of the sense of security that work gives
them compared to the uncertainty of looking for
work. The ambition of child workers in the case of
roadside hotel workers however was an exception
in that about 60% of them wanted to change their
jobs. This is mainly because in this profession
working hours are extremely long (See Table-7)
and revolved late night work with very little sleep,
and severe penalties for mistakes.
CONCLUSIONS:
In this paper I have argued briefly that both child mal
nutrition and child work emerge out of the
phenomenon of poverty in the Third World. The
problem is not one of production of food as much as
access to it; just as the problem of Child Work is not
so much a problem of effective legislation as the
imperative to work in families whose adult members
are unable to earn enough to provide for the children.
I have argued that poverty in many Third World
countries may arise out of the particular form of
economic growth they have adopted. I have used the
case of Pakistan to illustrate how rapid economic
growth if it is based on an unequal distribution of
productive assets, may generate affluence for the few
and poverty for the many. REFERENCES
1. The State of the World Children 1982.83. UNICEF,
Out, Oxford Page 4.
2. Ibid.
3. Ibid Page 5.
4. Ibid Page 27.
5. Akmal Hussain: Pakistan: The Nature and Origins
of the Crisis of the State. Chapter In Pakistan,
Politics and the State. ed. A Khan Zed Press,
London 1985.
6. Ibid.
7. Ibid.
8. Irfan and Ahmed Changes in Output, Employment,
Costs and Productivity. Unpublished. Mimeo 1985.
9. Akmal Hussain; Technical Change and Social
Polarization in Rural Punjab. Chapter in book; The
Political Economy of Rural Development. ed. K.
All. Vanguard Books, Lahore 1984.
10. Akmal Hussain: Report on Rural Population
Estimates. Study for the National Human
Settlements Policy, Government of Pakistan,
Environment and Urban Affairs Division. March
1988. Pg. 30.
11. Ibid. Table 1
CHANGE IN THE QUANTITY AND QUALITY OF THE DIET OF FARMERS
BETWEEN 1965 AND 1978 BY SIZE CLASS OF FARM
Size of Farm
Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has Improved
Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has
Deteriorated
Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has remained
unchanged
Total Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has Improved
Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has
Deteriorated
Percentage
No. of
Farmers
whose Diet
has remained
unchanged
Total
a B c d e f g H
Less then 8
8 to < 25
25 to <50
50 to < 150
150 and above
11
0
0
0
0
33
25
0
0
0
56
75
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
0
0
0
0
0
67
69
25
0
0
33
31
75
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
Source: Field Survey 1978 , Akmal Hussain.
Note: (1) Quantity of Diet, A reduction in the quantity of diet refers to a reduction in the quantity of one or more of the following items, without an increase in any:
(1) Number of Chappatis consumed during the day. (ii) Quantity of milk consumed during the day. (iii) Quantity of lassi consumed during the day (iv)
Number of times during the day lentils over vegetables are eaten along with Chappatis.
(2) Quantity of Diet, A reduction in the quantity of diet refers to a reduction in the quantity of one or more of the following items, without an increase in any:
(1) Number of Chappatis consumed during the day. (ii) Quantity of milk consumed during the day. (iii) Quantity of lassi consumed during the day (iv)
Number of times during the day lentils over vegetables are eaten along with Chappatis. Table 2
AVERAGE SHARE OF CHILD LABOUR TO FAMILY
INCOME-BY PROFESSION AND AGE
Age Profession
Under 9 9-11 12-14 All ages
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
1
0
0
5
0
2
4
3
0
0
5
4
10
11
14
9
22
8
0
0
7
7
20
9
19
15
31
25
11
18
6
6
17
9
18
12
24
17
11
18
All professions 3 9 15 13
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985.
Note: Indicates no interviews in the group. Table 3
AVERAGE MONTHLY TOTAL WAGES (CASH+
BENEFITS) BY PROFESSION & AGE
Age Profession
Under 9 9-11 12-14 All ages
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
50
0
0
152
0
110
200
125
0
0
181
137
265
280
155
265
423
200
0
0
232
263
510
254
325
125
432
516
366
336
193
213
437
239
311
346
406
375
366
336
All professions 130 243 367 322
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985.
Note: *Indicates no interviews in the group. Table 4
EDUCATIONAL LEVEL OF CHILD WORKER – BY
PROFESSION
PERCENTAGE
Education Profession None Primary Middle
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
70
50
60
80
80
80
70
50
20
70
30
50
10
20
20
20
30
40
70
30
0
0
30
0
0
0
0
10
10
0
All professions 630 32 5
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985. Table 5
PERCENTAGE OF CHILD WORKERS WHO
CONSIDER EDUCATION AS USEFUL – BY
PROFESSION
PERCENTAGE
Profession Percentage
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
70
100
80
70
90
80
90
90
90
100
All professions 86
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985. Table 6
AVERAGE NO OF DAYS CHILD WORKERS PLAY IN
A WEEK - BY AGE AND PROFESSION
Age Profession
Under 9 9-11 12-14 All ages
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
1
0
0
4
0
7
0
4
0
0
1
2
5
0
7
7
2
0
0
0
3
2
1
4
2
2
1
0
1
2
2
2
3
3
3
4
1
1
1
2
All professions 3 3 2 2
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985.
Note: * Indicates no interviews in the group. Table 7
AVERAGE NO OF WORKING HOURS PER DAY
BY PROFESSION AND AGE
Age Profession
Under 9 9-11 12-14 All ages
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
10
*
*
8
*
8
12
8
*
*
9
10
10
9
4
8
13
9
*
*
10
10
11
9
4
8
11
8
10
9
10
10
11
9
4
8
12
8
10
9
All professions 9 9 9 9
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985.
Note: * Indicates no interviews in the group. Table 8
AMBITION OF CHILD WORKERS FOR
NEXT FIVE YEARS BY PROFESSION
Age
Profession
Study
Continue
Present
Job
Change
Job
Go
Abroad
Lathe Machines
Automobiles
Service Station
Welding
Sweepers
Carpets
Roadside Hotels
Cobblers
Tailoring
Tin Packing
10
0
30
10
20
0
10
10
0
0
70
60
30
50
40
90
10
20
30
100
0
0
0
10
30
0
60
20
0
0
20
40
40
30
10
10
20
50
70
0
All professions 9 50 12 29
Source: Child Labour in Lahore, Sayyed Engineers’ Survey October
1985.
No comments:
Post a Comment